1991
DOI: 10.2307/2233865
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Role of Carbon Taxes in Adjusting to Global Warming

Abstract: JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

5
298
0
29

Year Published

1998
1998
2016
2016

Publication Types

Select...
8
2

Relationship

0
10

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 705 publications
(332 citation statements)
references
References 0 publications
5
298
0
29
Order By: Relevance
“…While there is much evidence supporting the Irish government's view that implementing a carbon tax is a cost-effective method of achieving a significant cut in CO 2 emissions (see, for example, Pearce, 1991, or McIlven and Helm, 2010), the evidence from countries which have already imposed this tax is mixed (Lin and Li, 2011). In light of this proposed budgetary measure we aim to assess the costs and benefits of a carbon tax in Ireland.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…While there is much evidence supporting the Irish government's view that implementing a carbon tax is a cost-effective method of achieving a significant cut in CO 2 emissions (see, for example, Pearce, 1991, or McIlven and Helm, 2010), the evidence from countries which have already imposed this tax is mixed (Lin and Li, 2011). In light of this proposed budgetary measure we aim to assess the costs and benefits of a carbon tax in Ireland.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The 1994 Oslo Symposium on sustainable consumption has established that the principles of democracy and the reality of control limitations demand that changes in consumption patterns be achieved not by force (e.g., bans) but rather through responsible consumer choices (Scammon and Mayer 1993) facilitated by the provision of independent information on markets. Because they allow for freedom of choice and avoid distorting market prices (Pearce 1991), labelling practices tend to be a preferred option to attain various objectives; for example, nutrition labels serve public health objectives (Mannell et al 2006), and environmental labels aim to achieve ecological goals (see Koos 2011). In the food sector, official organic labels attempt to promote the development of organic farming and more sustainable consumption (Thøgersen 2000).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…4 Early papers in the double dividend literature argued that because of that gain from recycling revenue, environmental taxes would still be worthwhile even if the pollutant being taxed turned out to be harmless: that the efficiency gain from revenue-recycling would more than cover the efficiency cost of the tax. That was a particularly attractive argument in the case of a carbon tax, because at the time the early double-dividend papers were written, there was still significant scientific uncertainty about the relationship between anthropogenic carbon emissions and climate change (and it remains a potentially attractive political argument even today, given 2 See, for example, Tullock (1967), Pearce (1991), Repetto (1992), and Oates (1995). 3 The terms "revenue-recycling effect" and "tax-interaction effect" are due to Goulder (1995).…”
Section: Environmental Taxes As Part Of the Broader Tax Systemmentioning
confidence: 99%