2018
DOI: 10.1111/mafi.12199
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The robust pricing–hedging duality for American options in discrete time financial markets

Abstract: We investigate the pricing–hedging duality for American options in discrete time financial models where some assets are traded dynamically and others, for example, a family of European options, only statically. In the first part of the paper, we consider an abstract setting, which includes the classical case with a fixed reference probability measure as well as the robust framework with a nondominated family of probability measures. Our first insight is that, by considering an enlargement of the space, we can … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2

Citation Types

0
42
0

Year Published

2019
2019
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
6

Relationship

1
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 32 publications
(42 citation statements)
references
References 51 publications
0
42
0
Order By: Relevance
“…The study of American-style claims in a robust framework was initiated by Neuberger [25]; see also Hobson and Neuberger [20], Bayraktar and Zhou [3] and Aksamit et al [1]. (There is also a paper by Cox and Hoeggerl [10] which asks about the possible shapes of the price of an American put, considered as a function of strike, given the prices of co-maturing European puts.)…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The study of American-style claims in a robust framework was initiated by Neuberger [25]; see also Hobson and Neuberger [20], Bayraktar and Zhou [3] and Aksamit et al [1]. (There is also a paper by Cox and Hoeggerl [10] which asks about the possible shapes of the price of an American put, considered as a function of strike, given the prices of co-maturing European puts.)…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Here, we consider an abstract general setup and allow any d-tuple of traded assets, for a finite d. We may expect that the level of uncertainty regarding different assets may differ and this would be reflected in P. However it is crucial that all the assets are traded dynamically. From a theoretical standpoint, this is both necessary to obtain a dynamic programming principle for the superhedging prices and without loss of generality in the sense that any Bouchard and Nutz [2015] setup where some assets are only available for trading at time 0 can be lifted to a setup with dynamic trading in all assets in a way which does not introduce arbitrage and does not affect time-0 superhedging prices, see Aksamit et al [2018]. From a practical standpoint, this is not a significant assumption as we may only consider liquidly traded assets.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Remark 4.1. The result still holds and the proof still goes through with minor adjustments, if we weaken/replace the assumption by:(1) there exists T ⊂ [0, 1] that is dense in [0, 1], such that (A s ∩ C [s,t] )• (X s , X t ) −1 is convex and closed for any s, t ∈ T with s < t; (2) A s ∩ C [s,t] is weakly compact for any s, t ∈ T with s < t; (3) the consistency assumption (4.1).Example 4.1 (Martingale measures with volatility uncertainty).Let Ω = C[0, 1] with X = R d . Assume α t has a finite first moment for any t ∈ [0, 1].…”
mentioning
confidence: 92%
“…In this section, we consider two cases Ω = C[0,1] or D[0, 1]. For t ∈ [0, 1], let Ω t = C[0, t], D[0, t]when Ω = C[0, 1], D[0, 1] respectively, Ω x t ⊂ Ω t be the set of paths starting from position x ∈ X.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%