2016
DOI: 10.1257/aer.20140316
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Politics of Compromise

Abstract: Many organizations rely on their members to develop solutions to specific problems. Universities establish search committees to hire at the senior level or to recommend changes to the curriculum. In a very similar fashion, standards bodies routinely form working groups to define the properties of a new technological standard. In both settings, there are no readily available solutions (i.e., candidates, curricula, standards) from which to select. Instead, the members of the organization must invest time and eff… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
36
0

Year Published

2016
2016
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 39 publications
(39 citation statements)
references
References 47 publications
1
36
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Furthermore, an increase in α also raises q 1 , the effect of which may go either way (see Proposition 6). Bonatti and Rantakari (2016) show that raising the super-majority requirement (γ) and implementing a rule removing projects that have not been adopted from further consideration (which corresponds to α = 0 in our setup) can induce project proposers to compromise, thus moving the proposed projects closer to the socially optimal ones. This provides a rationale for the evidence in Baron and Spulber (2015), according to which most SSOs require a super-majority, rather than a simple majority or unanimity, and for the prevalence of rules discarding proposals that have been voted down.…”
Section: Proposition 7 a Necessary Condition For Q 1 < 1 Is γ > (1 +mentioning
confidence: 94%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Furthermore, an increase in α also raises q 1 , the effect of which may go either way (see Proposition 6). Bonatti and Rantakari (2016) show that raising the super-majority requirement (γ) and implementing a rule removing projects that have not been adopted from further consideration (which corresponds to α = 0 in our setup) can induce project proposers to compromise, thus moving the proposed projects closer to the socially optimal ones. This provides a rationale for the evidence in Baron and Spulber (2015), according to which most SSOs require a super-majority, rather than a simple majority or unanimity, and for the prevalence of rules discarding proposals that have been voted down.…”
Section: Proposition 7 a Necessary Condition For Q 1 < 1 Is γ > (1 +mentioning
confidence: 94%
“…If there are two proposals on the table, then it chooses B 1 's with probability β and B 2 's with probability 1 − β. Like the rest of the literature (e.g., Farrell and Simcoe, 2012;Bonatti and Rantakari, 2016), we rule out side payments between participants.…”
Section: The Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Bonatti and Rantakari () show that raising the super‐majority requirement (γ) and implementing a rule removing projects that have not been adopted from further consideration (which corresponds to α=0 in our setup) can induce project proposers to compromise, thus moving the proposed projects closer to the socially optimal ones. This provides a rationale for the evidence in Baron and Spulber (), according to which most SSOs require a super‐majority, rather than a simple majority or unanimity, and for the existence of rules discarding proposals that have been voted down.…”
Section: Repeated Standard Settingmentioning
confidence: 98%
“…It would be interesting to see whether and how centralization would help to resolve this trade o §. In a related setting, Bonatti and Rantakari (2015) consider a setting where two agents choose which project to develop. To successfully develop a project, an agent exerts e §ort until a success occurs.…”
Section: Relation To the Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%