2015
DOI: 10.1016/j.eneco.2015.01.002
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The political economy of OPEC

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
5
0

Year Published

2015
2015
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
9

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 16 publications
(6 citation statements)
references
References 36 publications
0
5
0
Order By: Relevance
“…While some argue strictly that OPEC does not show cartelisation behaviour and should not be regarded as a such (Colgan, 2014;Kisswani, 2016;Plaut, 1981;Reynolds and Pippenger, 2010), others acknowledge OPEC's nature as a cartel but with limited collusion and prices below perfect cartelisation (Almoguera et al, 2011;Huppmann and Holz, 2012;Okullo and Reynès, 2016). Domestic oil dependency and the role of oil for the international economy further complicate this debate by adding other possible objectives regarding geopolitics, welfare, and domestic stability to profit maximisation (Hochman and Zilberman, 2015;Kisswani, 2014;Schwarz, 2008). The same applies to non-monotonicities such as behaviour and effectiveness differing with the direction of price changes (Alkhathlan et al, 2014;Loutia et al, 2016) Obviously, the complicated, unclear nature of OPEC is a central challenge for modellers, who have to determine strategic objectives and the role of competition in the market.…”
Section: Understanding and Modelling Opecmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…While some argue strictly that OPEC does not show cartelisation behaviour and should not be regarded as a such (Colgan, 2014;Kisswani, 2016;Plaut, 1981;Reynolds and Pippenger, 2010), others acknowledge OPEC's nature as a cartel but with limited collusion and prices below perfect cartelisation (Almoguera et al, 2011;Huppmann and Holz, 2012;Okullo and Reynès, 2016). Domestic oil dependency and the role of oil for the international economy further complicate this debate by adding other possible objectives regarding geopolitics, welfare, and domestic stability to profit maximisation (Hochman and Zilberman, 2015;Kisswani, 2014;Schwarz, 2008). The same applies to non-monotonicities such as behaviour and effectiveness differing with the direction of price changes (Alkhathlan et al, 2014;Loutia et al, 2016) Obviously, the complicated, unclear nature of OPEC is a central challenge for modellers, who have to determine strategic objectives and the role of competition in the market.…”
Section: Understanding and Modelling Opecmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…These findings are fair with the dominant-competitive fringe theory. Hochman and Zilberman (2011) explain that OPEC is seen as the dominant price-setter with high proven crude oil reserves compared to Non-OPEC firms, and able to impose production quotas to its member countries and also non-member countries. OPEC are able to target revenue-based through spare capacity utilization compared to Non-OPEC, who required to produce at full capacity in order to bring production costs lower (Kaufman et al, 2008;R.Golombek et al2018).…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…There is some evidence that citizens from resource-rich countries believe that resource wealth should be distributed among the population, including by lowering the prices of the resource ( Chelminski, 2018 ). In some OPEC countries, there remains a belief that certain sections of society deserve some form of subsidized energy ( Hochman and Zilberman, 2015 ), and the same argument has been made in the Nigerian context ( Nwachukwu et al, 2013 ). Furthermore, support for pricing reform is clearly influenced by the extent to which those in the same community support reform ( Blankenship, Wong, and Urpelainen, 2019 ).…”
Section: Literature and Hypothesesmentioning
confidence: 93%