2016
DOI: 10.1016/j.tics.2016.08.007
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Naïve Utility Calculus: Computational Principles Underlying Commonsense Psychology

Abstract: We propose that human social cognition is structured around a basic understanding of ourselves and others as intuitive utility maximizers: From a young age, humans implicitly assume that agents choose goals and actions to maximize the rewards they expect to obtain relative to the costs they expect to incur. This "naïve utility calculus" lets both children and adults observe others' behavior and infer their beliefs and desires, their longer-term knowledge and preferences, and even their character: who is knowle… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1

Citation Types

4
80
1

Year Published

2017
2017
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

5
3

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 57 publications
(88 citation statements)
references
References 64 publications
(80 reference statements)
4
80
1
Order By: Relevance
“…The flexibility of children's inferences suggests that they may be supported by an abstract understanding of preferences (i.e., utility functions that underlie choices) rather than mere associations (Jara-Ettinger, Gweon, Schulz, & Tenenbaum, 2016). Around 18 months of age, children already understand that another agent's food preference may differ from their own (Repacholi & Gopnik, 1997) and provide food items that she likes even when it conflicts with their own preferences.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The flexibility of children's inferences suggests that they may be supported by an abstract understanding of preferences (i.e., utility functions that underlie choices) rather than mere associations (Jara-Ettinger, Gweon, Schulz, & Tenenbaum, 2016). Around 18 months of age, children already understand that another agent's food preference may differ from their own (Repacholi & Gopnik, 1997) and provide food items that she likes even when it conflicts with their own preferences.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For us to know what someone likes, she has to know it herself first. other people make decisions, and it may differ in important ways from how people actually make decisions (see Jara-Ettinger, Gweon, Schulz, & Tenenbaum, 2016). Under this account, agents' knowledge of the costs and rewards should influence their behavior in two ways.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This generative account, also known as the Rational Speech Act (RSA) model (10), provides precise and falsifiable behavioral predictions in a parsimonious framework for social signal 55 interpretation that can be extended from communication (10,12,13) to social perception (16,17) and interpersonal decision-making (18). However, no direct evidence is available suggesting that pragmatic interpretation indeed involves rational, context-specific simulation of speakers.…”
Section: Main Textmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Speakers are expected to compare candidate expressions to make a choice for best helping the audience recognize the intended meaning in a given context. In addition, listeners need to monitor 50 knowledge and beliefs shared with the speaker (common ground) for simulating speaker behavior based on mutual, rather than the listener's own private knowledge (4, 6).This generative account, also known as the Rational Speech Act (RSA) model (10), provides precise and falsifiable behavioral predictions in a parsimonious framework for social signal 55 interpretation that can be extended from communication (10,12,13) to social perception (16,17) and interpersonal decision-making (18). However, no direct evidence is available suggesting that pragmatic interpretation indeed involves rational, context-specific simulation of speakers.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation