1983
DOI: 10.1111/j.1468-0084.1983.mp45003002.x
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

THE IMPERFECT MARKET FOR TECHNOLOGY LICENSES*

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
2
1

Citation Types

1
95
0
1

Year Published

1990
1990
2017
2017

Publication Types

Select...
6
1
1

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 256 publications
(97 citation statements)
references
References 10 publications
(8 reference statements)
1
95
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…In a crosscountry survey of both licensors and licensees, Caves et al (1983) found several licensing agreements that included clauses specifically aimed at protecting one party from the other's opportunistic behavior. For example, exclusivity clauses are especially common when licensees must make technology-specific investments to commercialize the invention they have licensed in.…”
Section: Formal and Informal Institutionsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…In a crosscountry survey of both licensors and licensees, Caves et al (1983) found several licensing agreements that included clauses specifically aimed at protecting one party from the other's opportunistic behavior. For example, exclusivity clauses are especially common when licensees must make technology-specific investments to commercialize the invention they have licensed in.…”
Section: Formal and Informal Institutionsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Second, technology transactions often require highly specialized complementary investments by the buyer or the seller, who are consequently highly exposed to the risk of 'hold up' (Shane, 2002). Third, firms dealing with technology transactions often face 'small number' bargaining problems, as only a limited number of players in the market can supply or exploit a certain technology, or have access to the appropriate downstream assets to commercialize it (Caves et al 1983;Contractor, 1981;Pisano, 1990;Schilling & Steensma, 2002).…”
Section: Formal and Informal Institutionsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…A survey of patent licensors revealed that 27 per cent of licenses covered products for which there is no close substitute. See Caves, Crookell and Killing (1983). 4.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…These few available 'pairs' lead to small-numbers bargaining conditions on the market. Additionally, Caves, Crookell et al (1983) argued that the different parties involved in a transaction have asymmetrical access to knowledge about the technology, which leads to opportunistic behaviour. Furthermore, since technologies are usually transacted that still need certain developments until they can be fully utilized or a technology may not work properly at any new location for whatever reason (e.g.…”
Section: Growing Markets For Technologymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Teece (1986, p.303) noted that there are particularly "difficulties in pricing an intangible asset" which is not at least due to the unique nature of the good. Caves, Crookell et al (1983) analyzing international technology transfer to foreign countries in terms of licensing provided an argumentation that the market for technology licenses, like other markets for intangible knowledge, is "susceptible to market failures" resulting from five prevalent obstacles. At the time when they published their study, they had observed that typically only very few companies were willing to license a technology they possess, while on the other hand the demand of companies that feel a specific need for a certain technology was limited, according to Contractor (1981).…”
Section: Growing Markets For Technologymentioning
confidence: 99%