2021
DOI: 10.1086/712786
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Economic Structure of International Trade-in-Services Agreements

Abstract: Staiger gratefully acknowledges financial support from the National Science Foundation (NSF Grant SES-1326940). We thank Kyle Bagwell, Petros C. Mavroidis, Alan Spearot and seminar participants at Stanford for useful comments. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.Ą t least one co-author has disclosed a financial relationship of potential relevance for this research. Further information is available online at htt… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
5
0

Year Published

2021
2021
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
5
2

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 11 publications
(9 citation statements)
references
References 26 publications
0
5
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Contrary to tariffs, these nontariff policy dimensions embrace no government revenue-collection motive while still affecting the terms of trade and the spatial distribution of economic activity. Thus, our article adds to the growing literature on the economics of deep integration, moving beyond the notion of tariff-oriented trade agreements (see Grossman et al, 2021;Staiger and Sykes, 2021).…”
Section: Specific Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Contrary to tariffs, these nontariff policy dimensions embrace no government revenue-collection motive while still affecting the terms of trade and the spatial distribution of economic activity. Thus, our article adds to the growing literature on the economics of deep integration, moving beyond the notion of tariff-oriented trade agreements (see Grossman et al, 2021;Staiger and Sykes, 2021).…”
Section: Specific Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This article complements previous research on regulatory protection that either focuses on partial equilibrium effects (Baldwin, 2000; Fischer and Serra, 2000; Staiger and Sykes, 2011, 2020) or uses neoclassical trade models that include only the terms‐of‐trade effect (Bagwell and Staiger, 2001; Ederington, 2001; Maggi and Ossa, 2023). My model incorporates the forces found in earlier papers, but identifies a novel and important channel through which standards affect welfare: the adjustment in the number of varieties.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 87%
“…What, then, explains the striking di¤erence between GATT and GATS that I noted at the outset of this section? I now illustrate the key elements of the "missing tari¤ instrument" interpretation of this di¤erence put forward by Staiger and Sykes (2021).…”
Section: The Purpose Of Gats In a Pre-digital Worldmentioning
confidence: 93%
“…This issue arises, for example, when considering a good that is delivered from a foreign source via digital instructions for additive manufacturing ("3-D printing") in a domestic location. This issue is consequential because of the di¤erent structure and level of market access commitments in GATT (which applies to traded goods) and GATS (which applies to traded services), a di¤erence that re ‡ects in part the di¤erent policy instruments available to governments for in ‡uencing trade ‡ows across the goods and services sectors (see Staiger, 2018, andSykes, 2021).…”
Section: What Is Digital Trade?mentioning
confidence: 99%