2017
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3013537
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Temperature Shocks and Welfare Costs

Abstract: This paper examines the welfare implications of rising temperatures. Using a standard VAR, we empirically show that a temperature shock has a sizable, negative and statistically significant impact on TFP, output, and labor productivity. We rationalize these findings within a production economy featuring long-run temperature risk. In the model, macro-aggregates drop in response to a temperature shock, consistent with the novel evidence in the data. Such adverse effects are long-lasting. Over a 50-year horizon, … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

6
26
0
1

Year Published

2017
2017
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

4
3

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 18 publications
(33 citation statements)
references
References 39 publications
6
26
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…by setting the probability of rare disasters equal to zero. 24 Similarly, Donadelli et al (2017) compute the loss in the optimal consumption path that agents are willing to suffer to completely eliminate long-term temperature risk. 25 Given that our two representative countries differ only by the distributions of natural disaster shocks, our approach enables us to quantify how natural disasters (and in some 24 While in Barro (2009) rare disasters do not include natural events, Barro (2015) extends the former model to include the probability of environmental disasters.…”
Section: Climate Changementioning
confidence: 99%
See 3 more Smart Citations
“…by setting the probability of rare disasters equal to zero. 24 Similarly, Donadelli et al (2017) compute the loss in the optimal consumption path that agents are willing to suffer to completely eliminate long-term temperature risk. 25 Given that our two representative countries differ only by the distributions of natural disaster shocks, our approach enables us to quantify how natural disasters (and in some 24 While in Barro (2009) rare disasters do not include natural events, Barro (2015) extends the former model to include the probability of environmental disasters.…”
Section: Climate Changementioning
confidence: 99%
“…30 In particular, Barro (2009) calculates welfare losses of about 8-9% arising from the risk of rare disasters (not necessarily natural disasters). Similarly, Donadelli et al (2017) report welfare losses of 4.6% and 9.2% due to the long-run temperature risk, depending on the elasticity of productivity to temperature shocks. 31 Our welfare loss, despite being of the same order of magnitude, is lower because we calculate it relative to a calibration with less frequent and less damaging natural disasters.…”
Section: The Long-run Effects Of Natural Disastersmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Specifically, the model captures the long-lasting effect that global temperature has on world consumption growth observed in the data. Based on the empirical evidence that temperature shocks undermine TFP growth, Donadelli, Jüppner, Riedel, and Schlag (2017), following the approach of Bansal and Ochoa (2011b), integrate U.S. temperature dynamics into a production-based model featuring recursive preferences, long-run productivity risk, and investment adjustment costs. We differ from these theoretical approaches aiming at studying the macroeconomic effects of climate change-related phenomena in that we analyze the welfare implications of rising temperatures within a stochastic endogenous growth framework.…”
Section: Related Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%