2009
DOI: 10.1016/j.jmacro.2009.05.003
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Technological change and the roaring twenties: A neoclassical perspective

Abstract: Annualized output growth in the United States was highest during the 1920s, as compared to any other of Field's (2003, 2009) growth cycles. This motivates us to address the causes of the Roaring Twenties in the United States. In particular, we use a version of the real business cycle model to test the hypothesis that an extraordinary pace of productivity growth was the driving factor. Our motivation comes from the abundance of evidence of signi…cant technological progress during this period, fed by innovations… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
11
0

Year Published

2010
2010
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
6

Relationship

3
3

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 9 publications
(12 citation statements)
references
References 24 publications
1
11
0
Order By: Relevance
“…The introduction of a collateral constraint into this framework is likely to prove productive. In addition, Harrison and Weder (2009) examine the Roaring Twenties as a time of technological progress. Evidence of optimism during that decade bodes well for our model.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The introduction of a collateral constraint into this framework is likely to prove productive. In addition, Harrison and Weder (2009) examine the Roaring Twenties as a time of technological progress. Evidence of optimism during that decade bodes well for our model.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This interpretation of US economic growth is supported by other research. Harrison and Weder (2009) stress the very high total factor productivity growth of the 1920s as evidence of a supply-side technology based explanation of high US economic growth. Although Field (2011) raises some doubts about the idea of GPT he agrees with the productivity bonus effects of electricity use in manufacturing during the 1920s.…”
Section: A Productivity-bonus From Electricity Usage? Time Seriesmentioning
confidence: 91%
“…Δ K can be interpreted as investments not related to electricity. In line with conventional assumptions (see for example Harrison andWeder 2009, p. 366, or Field, 2011, p. 6) we set β = 0.7. This parameter is also consistent with the estimates of factor shares from Matthews et al (1982) for the interwar UK economy.…”
Section: Electricity Diffusion and Productivity: Disaggregated Evidenmentioning
confidence: 99%
“… US Total Factor Productivity (TFP), 1892–1941, Logarithmic Scale. The Lower Part of the Figure Shows the Deviations from Constant Time Trend ( Harrison and Weder, 2009 ) …”
Section: Supply Shocksmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The reason behind this failure is the rapid rise of TFP, which hovers significantly above its long run average from 1935 onwards (see Figure 2). In (Harrison and Weder, 2009) Temin's (1976) emphasis on contractions of real aggregate demand beginning with the market crash and continuing through the first years of the thirties. Temin's argument rests on an episodic pattern of consumption which bears no resemblance to that of other recessions.…”
Section: Supply Shocksmentioning
confidence: 99%