2000
DOI: 10.1257/aer.90.3.356
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Tax Policy and Aggregate Demand Management Under Catching Up with the Joneses

Abstract: This paper examines the role for tax policies in productivity-shock driven economies with catching-up-with-the-Joneses utility functions. The optimal tax policy is shown to affect the economy countercyclically via procyclical taxes, i.e., “cooling down” the economy with higher taxes when it is “overheating” in booms and “stimulating” the economy with lower taxes in recessions to keep consumption up. Thus, models with catching-up-with-the-Joneses utility functions call for traditional Keynesian demand-managemen… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

12
337
4

Year Published

2009
2009
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
4
3

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 384 publications
(353 citation statements)
references
References 11 publications
(10 reference statements)
12
337
4
Order By: Relevance
“…With mean value comparisons, each consumer contributes to the positional externalities to the same extent and the average degree of positionality, α , represents the value of the marginal externality per unit of consumption, which explains the second formula in the proposition. This welfarist tax formula is analogous to results derived in the context of representative agent models by, e.g., Ljungqvist and Uhlig (2000) and Dupor and Liu (2003), and of course also to the two-type model in Aronsson and Johansson-Stenman (2008).…”
Section: Corrective Policy In a First-best Settingsupporting
confidence: 62%
See 3 more Smart Citations
“…With mean value comparisons, each consumer contributes to the positional externalities to the same extent and the average degree of positionality, α , represents the value of the marginal externality per unit of consumption, which explains the second formula in the proposition. This welfarist tax formula is analogous to results derived in the context of representative agent models by, e.g., Ljungqvist and Uhlig (2000) and Dupor and Liu (2003), and of course also to the two-type model in Aronsson and Johansson-Stenman (2008).…”
Section: Corrective Policy In a First-best Settingsupporting
confidence: 62%
“…The present paper thus supplements earlier research based on the welfarist approach to first-best (e.g., Persson, 1995;Ljungqvist and Uhlig, 2000;Dupor and Liu, 2003) and second-best optimal income taxation (e.g., Johansson-Stenman, 2008, 2010) by considering the case where consumer preferences for relative standing are of no concern to the government. The point of departure is the discrete variant of the Mirrleesian optimal income tax model with two productivity types developed by Stern (1982) and Stiglitz (1982), which will be extended to accommodate consumer preferences for relative consumption, and where information asymmetries typically prevent the government from implementing a first-best resource allocation.…”
Section: Introductionsupporting
confidence: 54%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…The regulative role of taxation is one of the most pronounced roles from the fiscalists. The optimal tax policy turns out to affect the economy countercyclically via procyclical taxes, that is, "cooling down" the economy with higher taxes when it is "overheating" due to a positive productivity shock (Ljungqvist & Uhlig 2000). The explanation is that agents would otherwise end up consuming too much in boom times since they are not taking into account the "addiction effect" of a higher consumption level.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%