2010
DOI: 10.1007/s12064-010-0097-5
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Taking evolution seriously in political science

Abstract: In this essay, we explore the epistemological and ontological assumptions that have been made to make political science ''scientific.'' We show how political science has generally adopted an ontologically reductionist philosophy of science derived from Newtonian physics and mechanics. This mechanical framework has encountered problems and constraints on its explanatory power, because an emphasis on equilibrium analysis is ill-suited for the study of political change. We outline the primary differences between … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
16
0
1

Year Published

2012
2012
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
5
2
2

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 47 publications
(18 citation statements)
references
References 49 publications
0
16
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…6–7; see Klijn, 2008, p. 314, on ‘wicked’, or apparently intractable, policy problems). Many accounts also use it to challenge their idea of rational choice theory (Geyer and Rihani, 2010, p. 5; Lewis and Steinmo, 2008, pp. 15–20; 2010, p. 237; Little, 2008, pp.…”
Section: What Is Complexity Theory?mentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…6–7; see Klijn, 2008, p. 314, on ‘wicked’, or apparently intractable, policy problems). Many accounts also use it to challenge their idea of rational choice theory (Geyer and Rihani, 2010, p. 5; Lewis and Steinmo, 2008, pp. 15–20; 2010, p. 237; Little, 2008, pp.…”
Section: What Is Complexity Theory?mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Second, RCT and complexity can both be linked to the pursuit of evolutionary theory (albeit partly because this is an approach, like new institutionalism, with many variants). For example, Lewis and Steinmo (2008) use evolutionary arguments largely to reject RCT, but they also acknowledge (with reference to Axelrod, 1984) the value of evolutionary game theory and the centrality of the trial-and-error strategies of individuals to accounts of generational change in political science. 2 See also Klijn (2008) for a link to the literature on governance, multiple streams analysis and game theory.…”
Section: Notesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Historical, sociological and rational choice institutionalism typically applies heavy doses of institutional conditioning, ending up with essentially ‘structuralist’ or overly ‘sticky’ accounts of institutional life, depicting institutions as rule‐bound, highly constraining and as either resistant to change or as shaping change along defined paths. Building on earlier work that has given greater emphasis to institutionally situated agency (Campbell, ; Crouch, ; Lewis and Steinmo, ; Mahoney and Thelen, ; Streeck and Thelen, ; Thelen and Steinmo, ), Bell () presents an approach which emphasises that agents and institutions are mutually shaping over time. Bell () has recently extended this approach by emphasising the role of wider ‘meta‐institutional’ contexts in shaping institutional change.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Generalized Darwinism thus provides an overarching meta-theoretical framework which is useful and meaningful at an abstract rather than detail level (Aldrich et al, 2008;Hodgson, 2013;Hodgson and Knudsen, 2010). 3 In short, while Lewis and Steinmo's (2006) call for 'taking evolution seriously' can be seen as an attempt to raise the level of interaction between social and biological evolutionary theory from metaphor to analogy according to Cohen's hierarchy, in more recent years the two authors have moved beyond the metaphor-analogy mindset by reframing their analysis under the perspective of generalized Darwinism -an idea that does not rely on any assumption of metaphorical or analogous similarities or differences.…”
Section: T a K I N G E V O L U T I O N S E R I O U S L Y O R M E T mentioning
confidence: 99%