1999
DOI: 10.1016/s0954-349x(98)00049-6
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Sustainable greenhouse policies: the role of non-CO2 gases

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
7
0
2

Year Published

2006
2006
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
7
2

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 17 publications
(10 citation statements)
references
References 13 publications
1
7
0
2
Order By: Relevance
“…By including non-CO 2 gases and using GWPs, the costs of climate policy decrease only by around 10%. This is about twice as much as Michaelis (1999) found using a similar but simpler model. Second, the additional cost savings from the flexible refinement as compared to using fixed GWPs is about 2%, which is very similar to what reported by O'Neill (2003).…”
Section: Some Limitations and Concluding Remarkssupporting
confidence: 62%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…By including non-CO 2 gases and using GWPs, the costs of climate policy decrease only by around 10%. This is about twice as much as Michaelis (1999) found using a similar but simpler model. Second, the additional cost savings from the flexible refinement as compared to using fixed GWPs is about 2%, which is very similar to what reported by O'Neill (2003).…”
Section: Some Limitations and Concluding Remarkssupporting
confidence: 62%
“…in the calculations (see e.g Michaelis, 1999). It is, however, unclear whether possible rate dependent impacts are well represented by such a function, especially within an optimization model.…”
Section: A Flexible Multi-gas Climate Policymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Note that such reasoning would not hold if equation (10) had a constraint on the rate of warming, rather than its level. 19 When the constraint does not bind, the ratio of marginal costs in the least-cost solution can be expressed as a purely physical ratio [51]. 20 Reference [33] derives a variation of the GTP called the cost-effective temperature potential (CETP) that assumes the shadow price is constant once the constraint is reached, and therefore it also drops out of that metric.…”
Section: Cost-effectiveness Analysis: Global Temperature Change Potenmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…It has been confirmed by a number of studies, which, following up on the aforementioned pioneering works, proposed alternative indices (Kandlikar, 1995;Kandlikar, 1996;Hammit et al, 1996;Bradford and Keller, 2000;Manne and Richels, 2001;Shine et al, 2005) or provided empirical assessments of the concept's implications (Michaelis, 1999;Smith and Wigley, 2000;O'Neil, 2000;Tol et al, 2003;O'Neil, 2003;Kurosawa, 2004;Sarofim et al, 2005). See Fuglestvedt et al (2003) for a comprehensive review.…”
mentioning
confidence: 91%