2009
DOI: 10.1111/j.1468-2354.2009.00560.x
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Subjective Probabilities in Games: An Application to the Overbidding Puzzle*

Abstract: This article illustrates how the joint elicitation of subjective probabilities and preferences may help us understand behavior in games. We conduct an experiment to test whether biased probabilistic beliefs may explain overbidding in first-price auctions. The experimental outcomes indicate that subjects underestimate their probability of winning the auction, and indeed overbid. When provided with feedback on the precision of their predictions, subjects learn to make better predictions, and to curb significantl… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2

Citation Types

6
55
0

Year Published

2010
2010
2018
2018

Publication Types

Select...
6

Relationship

0
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 57 publications
(61 citation statements)
references
References 54 publications
6
55
0
Order By: Relevance
“…(1926) suggests to minimize distortions arising from risk preferences by paying small stakes. However, Armantier and Treich (2013) prove that this does not necessary solve the problem. Paying small stakes only reduces biases when subjects display increasing relative risk aversion, and worsens it for decreasing relative risk aversion.…”
Section: Incentivized Elicitation When Subjects Are Not Risk Neutralmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…(1926) suggests to minimize distortions arising from risk preferences by paying small stakes. However, Armantier and Treich (2013) prove that this does not necessary solve the problem. Paying small stakes only reduces biases when subjects display increasing relative risk aversion, and worsens it for decreasing relative risk aversion.…”
Section: Incentivized Elicitation When Subjects Are Not Risk Neutralmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For example, under the QSR a risk averse subject should submit reports that are biased away from extreme outcomes in order to minimize losses. Using the QSR, Offerman et al (2009) and Armantier and Treich (2013) provide evidence that subjects do indeed report beliefs that are consistent with such a strategy.…”
Section: Incentivized Elicitation When Subjects Are Not Risk Neutralmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Various answers have been proposed, as in e.g., Armantier and Treich (2009), Rogers, Camerer and Palfrey (2009) and Camerer, Nunnari and Palfrey (2016). 2 Although making these modifications shows that assuming heterogeneity in agents' traits considerably improves the model's goodness-of-fit, it does not address the question of when one should indeed forego the assumption of homogeneous agents.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…3 We also note a subtle difference between empiricists and experimentalists regarding the definition of unobserved heterogeneity in the structural analysis of game-theoretic models. The former define it as information that is available to agents but not to the researcher (Paarsch and Hong, 2006) whereas the latter assume that the researcher is aware of this information and uses it to assess the model's explanatory power (e.g., Armantier andTreich, 2009, and. See Kirman (2006) for an overview of the role of heterogeneity in economics and Branch and McGough (2018) for a discussion of the role of heterogeneous expectations in macroeconomics.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation