1990
DOI: 10.1016/0022-0531(90)90003-3
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Subgame perfect implementation: A necessary and almost sufficient condition

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

0
111
0

Year Published

1996
1996
2003
2003

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

1
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 134 publications
(111 citation statements)
references
References 8 publications
0
111
0
Order By: Relevance
“…2 The set of individuals is denoted by x f1Y 2Y F F F Y ng. Let i be a ®nite set of possible states of endowment vectors, let i be a ®nite set of possible types for agent i, and let i i  i .…”
Section: The Framework Of Analysismentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…2 The set of individuals is denoted by x f1Y 2Y F F F Y ng. Let i be a ®nite set of possible states of endowment vectors, let i be a ®nite set of possible types for agent i, and let i i  i .…”
Section: The Framework Of Analysismentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For complete information environments, characterization results were given by Maskin [14], Hurwicz, Maskin, Postlewaite [12], Repullo [28], Sajio [29], Moore and Repullo [19], Dutta and Sen [5], Danilov [4], and others for Nash implementation; Moore and Repullo [18], Abreu and Sen [2] and others for implementation using re®ne-ments of Nash equilibrium; Matsushima [15] and Abreu and Sen [3] for virtual Nash implementation. For incomplete information environments, characterization results were given by Postlewaite and Schmeidler [25], Palfrey, and Srivastava [20,21], Mookherjee and Reichelstein [17], Jackson [13], Hong [9] among many others for Bayesian implementation; by Palfrey and Srivastava [23] and Mookherjee and Reichelstein [17] for implementation in using re®nements of Bayesian equilibrium; Abreu and Matsushima [1], Matsushima [16], Duggan [7], and Tian [35] for virtual Bayesian implementation.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Monotonicity (Maskin (1999)), a necessary condition for Nash implementation, is violated for allocations at the boundary of the feasible set. However, we know since the seminal work of Moore-Repullo (1988) and Abreu-Sen (1990) that monotonicity is no longer necessary for subgame perfect implementation. We …rst show that the Walrasian correspondence de…ned over this class of exchange economies is not implementable in subgame perfect equilibrium.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For instance, for a class of exchange economies in which preferences are continuous, convex and strongly monotone, it is now well-known that the Walrasian correspondence is not monotonic, (see, e.g., Hurwicz-Maskin-Postlewaite (1995)). The violation of monotonicity occurs for Walrasian allocations that are at the boundary of the feasible set 1 . Hurwicz (1979) and Schmeidler (1980) have constructed mechanisms that implement the Walrasian correspondence but in which o¤ equilibrium allocations may award negative quantities to some agents.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Within the context of implementation theory there have been significant developments in the characterization of social choice rules that can be implemented in dominant strategies [20,32]; in Nash equilibria [83-85, 112, 143]; or in refined Nash equilibria such as subgame perfect equilibria [2,87], undominated Nash equilibria [1,46,48,96], trembling hand perfect Nash equilibria [123]; or in Bayesian Nash equilibria [45,95,97,106]. Excellent survey articles on implementation theory are [47,85,94].…”
Section: Definition 5 a Social Choice Correspondence π : E → A Is Samentioning
confidence: 99%