2013
DOI: 10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2013.02.002
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Strategies for cooperation in biological markets, especially for humans

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
4
1

Citation Types

14
303
0
1

Year Published

2013
2013
2016
2016

Publication Types

Select...
5
2
1

Relationship

1
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 283 publications
(318 citation statements)
references
References 120 publications
14
303
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…It has been argued that a good reputation could not only allow for partner choice in cooperative interactions or receiving more help in future interactions (Alexander, 1987;Roberts, 1998), but also that it might be linked to the actor's quality (Zahavi, 1977), serving as an honest signal conveying information on the actor's resources, capabilities or reproductive quality for example (Barclay, 2013;Fehrler & Przepiorka, 2013;Tognetti et al, 2014). Consequently, costs of generosity in collective action dilemmas might be outweighed in other various contexts.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…It has been argued that a good reputation could not only allow for partner choice in cooperative interactions or receiving more help in future interactions (Alexander, 1987;Roberts, 1998), but also that it might be linked to the actor's quality (Zahavi, 1977), serving as an honest signal conveying information on the actor's resources, capabilities or reproductive quality for example (Barclay, 2013;Fehrler & Przepiorka, 2013;Tognetti et al, 2014). Consequently, costs of generosity in collective action dilemmas might be outweighed in other various contexts.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Such a straightforward reputational mechanism enhances cooperation frequency and allows cooperative members of a group to recognise and trust each other (Nowak & Sigmund, 1998;Wedekind & Braithwaite, 2002;Wedekind & Milinski, 2000;Yoeli et al, 2013) and to benefit from choosing their partners (Fu et al, 2008;Sylwester & Roberts, 2010), creating a biological market based on cooperativeness, i.e. competition among potential partners to be chosen for social interactions (Barclay, 2013).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…One 25 way this can be achieved is if helpful individuals are preferred as partners: giving players the option to either avoid bad partners or actively choose good ones increases cooperation, compared to interactions where individuals are forced to interact with one another [1][2][3][4][5]. Biological market theory [5][6][7] predicts that individuals prefer the 'best' possible partners for interactions. But what does 'best' actually mean?…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…But what does 'best' actually mean? In the context of cooperation, the best partners are those who are most 30 able and most willing to confer benefits on others [7][8][9]. In hunter-gatherer societies, for example, those who hunt successfully and are also willing to share the spoils with others form more profitable relationships than those who are successful but do not share [10].…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…A reputation based on punishment, for example, may have played a key role in the evolution of punishment that promotes cooperation within groups (Brandt et al, 2003;Gardner and West, 2004;Hilbe and Sigmund, 2010;dos Santos et al, 2011dos Santos et al, , 2013. Various kinds of reputation may therefore affect partner choice (Fu et al, 2008;Sylwester and Roberts, 2010) and may thereby create a biological market (Barclay, 2013).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%