2015
DOI: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2015.03.031
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Statistical inference for panel dynamic simultaneous equations models

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

2
11
0

Year Published

2015
2015
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

2
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 22 publications
(13 citation statements)
references
References 23 publications
(23 reference statements)
2
11
0
Order By: Relevance
“…The first column of Table 3 reports the marginal effects from a (doubly) censored regression model (Greene, 2012) in which the dependent variable is the individual contribution of subject i in period t. 17 We have the following explanatory variables: Is Punishing g,t , a binary covariate that equals 1 if a sanctioning mechanism is in place in i's current group g, and 0 otherwise; Initial Group i,t , a dummy taking the value 1 if i is located in the group she was allocated to at the beginning of the experiment, and 0 otherwise; Group Contribution g[−i],t−1 , the average contribution of the other members of i's current group in 16 For ease of exposition, we estimate the models and present results for each of these outcomes separately. The findings reported below are generally similar if we fit panel dynamic simultaneous equations models, even though standard estimation approaches (e.g., Akashi and Kunitomo, 2012;Hsiao and Zhou, 2015) require ignoring the censoring of contributions and the dichotomous nature of migration and voting decisions.…”
Section: Individual Behaviorsupporting
confidence: 54%
“…The first column of Table 3 reports the marginal effects from a (doubly) censored regression model (Greene, 2012) in which the dependent variable is the individual contribution of subject i in period t. 17 We have the following explanatory variables: Is Punishing g,t , a binary covariate that equals 1 if a sanctioning mechanism is in place in i's current group g, and 0 otherwise; Initial Group i,t , a dummy taking the value 1 if i is located in the group she was allocated to at the beginning of the experiment, and 0 otherwise; Group Contribution g[−i],t−1 , the average contribution of the other members of i's current group in 16 For ease of exposition, we estimate the models and present results for each of these outcomes separately. The findings reported below are generally similar if we fit panel dynamic simultaneous equations models, even though standard estimation approaches (e.g., Akashi and Kunitomo, 2012;Hsiao and Zhou, 2015) require ignoring the censoring of contributions and the dichotomous nature of migration and voting decisions.…”
Section: Individual Behaviorsupporting
confidence: 54%
“…Baltagi, 1981), many of the econometric challenges inherent in growth-related applications have been solved more recently. This is especially true for dynamic models (Hsiao & Zhou, 2015) and for spatial methods (see below; X. Liu & Saraiva, 2019;Yang & Lee, 2019).…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Maximizing the logarithm of (2.7), (θ) with respect to θ = (φ , σ ), where σ denotes the unknown elements of Ω * yields the (transformed) (quasi) maximum likelihood estimator (QMLE) (Binder, Hsiao and Pesaran (2005)). The QMLE with properly formulated initial conditions is asymptotically unbiased independent of the way N or T or both tend to infinity (Hsiao and Zhou (2014)).…”
Section: )mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Alternatively, Hsiao and Zhou (2014) show that the likelihood approach with properly formulated initial value distribution for ỹ i0 yields an estimator that is asymptotically unbiased independent of the way N or T or both tend to infinity. However, maximizing the (transformed) likelihood function of (Δỹ i2 , .…”
Section: Dynamic Simultaneous Equations Modelsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation