1992
DOI: 10.1086/261855
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Social Norms, Savings Behavior, and Growth

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

8
427
2
4

Year Published

2000
2000
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
8
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 519 publications
(475 citation statements)
references
References 14 publications
8
427
2
4
Order By: Relevance
“…For example, Robson [120] considers how a concern for status and an attendant riskpreference might arise in a polygynous setting, where females choose males based on their wealth. Cole, Mailath and Postlewaite [26] suggest that concerns for status may arise because some goods in our economy are allocated not by prices, but by nonmarket mechanisms in which status plays a role. Cole, Mailath and Postlewaite suggest the "marriage market" as a prime such example, where access to desirable mates often hinges on placing well in a status ordering that depends importantly on wealth.…”
Section: Risk and Statusmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For example, Robson [120] considers how a concern for status and an attendant riskpreference might arise in a polygynous setting, where females choose males based on their wealth. Cole, Mailath and Postlewaite [26] suggest that concerns for status may arise because some goods in our economy are allocated not by prices, but by nonmarket mechanisms in which status plays a role. Cole, Mailath and Postlewaite suggest the "marriage market" as a prime such example, where access to desirable mates often hinges on placing well in a status ordering that depends importantly on wealth.…”
Section: Risk and Statusmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…These studies find that, in addition to their own levels of consumption, individuals care about their peers' consumption levels and their wealth rank relative to their comparison group, which validates the use of reduced-form models such as equation 1. For instance, see Cole et al (1992); Corneo and Jeanne (1997);. Boskin and Sheshinski (1978) and Oswald (1983) theoretically analyze tax policy implications of relative utility, while Abel (1990); Bakshi and Chen (1996); Gali (1994);and Campbell and Cochrane (1999) examined such relative effects on asset pricing.…”
Section: Data Descriptionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Indeed, our formulation does not even require the knowledge of precisely what this individual 7 As noted earlier, the appeal of``doing better than others'' may even be a direct consequence of the primitives of an economic model. One such example is provided by Cole et al (1992) within the context of a matching model where (independent) utility maximization leads to the desire of having a better standing (in terms of relative wealth) in the society than others. regards as``status''; this information is implicit in the agent's preference relation x.…”
Section: Negative Interdependence and Spitementioning
confidence: 99%
“…' Veblen (1899, p. 32)1 This basic insight has later been reformulated in several distinct ways to capture the notion that one's well-being is determined not only by the intrinsic utility of her material consumption, but also by one's relative standing (status) in the society or in her peer group (Duesenberry 1949, Easterlin 1974, Layard 1980, Frank 1985.2 In the economics literature, this notion is sometimes referred to as the relative income hypothesis, or as the phenomenon of keeping up with the Joneses, and is usually introduced to the models by postulating envious preferences on the part of the individuals. Furthermore, it is noted by several authors that, in some cases, the individuals may care about their relative standing in the society simply because a higher status implies better access to goods which the individuals value (Cole et al 1992).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%