2015
DOI: 10.3386/w21169
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Social Networks, Reputation and Commitment: Evidence from a Savings Monitors Experiment

Abstract: We conduct an experiment to study whether individuals save more when information about the progress toward their self‐set savings goal is shared with another village member (a “monitor”). We develop a reputational framework to explore how a monitor's effectiveness depends on her network position. Savers who care about whether others perceive them as responsible should save more with central monitors, who more widely disseminate information, and proximate monitors, who pass information to individuals with whom … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

5
61
0

Year Published

2016
2016
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
8
2

Relationship

1
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 41 publications
(66 citation statements)
references
References 33 publications
5
61
0
Order By: Relevance
“…The first method is random assignment, either of some intervention provided to a subset of nodes in the network, or of links in the network. Random assignments of interventions have been used to study a wide range of questions, including the diffusion of innovations in social networks (Aral and Walker, ; Oster and Thornton, ; Cai et al ., ; among others), social learning (Godlonton and Thornton, ), sharing of resources and savings (Comola and Prina, ; Angelucci et al ., forthcoming), peer effects in exercise (Babcock et al ., ), peer effects in education (Angelucci et al ., ; Babcock and Hartman, ) and peer monitoring (Breza and Chandrasekhar, ).…”
Section: Dealing With Endogeneity Of Network Formationmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The first method is random assignment, either of some intervention provided to a subset of nodes in the network, or of links in the network. Random assignments of interventions have been used to study a wide range of questions, including the diffusion of innovations in social networks (Aral and Walker, ; Oster and Thornton, ; Cai et al ., ; among others), social learning (Godlonton and Thornton, ), sharing of resources and savings (Comola and Prina, ; Angelucci et al ., forthcoming), peer effects in exercise (Babcock et al ., ), peer effects in education (Angelucci et al ., ; Babcock and Hartman, ) and peer monitoring (Breza and Chandrasekhar, ).…”
Section: Dealing With Endogeneity Of Network Formationmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…We discuss savings balances in the villages with endogenous monitor assignment in Section , and Section is a conclusion. Robustness exercises and extensions can be found in the Supplemental Material ( Breza and Chandrasekhar ()) and the Auxiliary Online Appendix (available on the authors' webpages at https://stanford.edu/~arungc/BC_aux.pdf).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…A growing literature suggests that people may fail to save because doing so is not salient (Taubinsky 2014;Karlan, McConnell, Mullainathan, Zinman, 2016); and, correspondingly, they might be induced to do save by reminders. In-person visits may also generate peer pressure (Kast, Meier, and Pomeranz, 2012;Chandrasekhar and Breza, 2015). Second, the collection service has a commitment feature: we reduce the cost of making deposits, but not withdrawals.…”
Section: Why Do Deposit Collections Increase Savings and Labor Effort?mentioning
confidence: 99%