2015
DOI: 10.1111/jmcb.12240
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Responding to a Shadow Banking Crisis: The Lessons of 1763

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1

Citation Types

0
6
0

Year Published

2016
2016
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
5
3

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 23 publications
(6 citation statements)
references
References 35 publications
0
6
0
Order By: Relevance
“…After the failure of a large banking house in August 1763, there were runs on merchant banks that had been financing themselves with short-term debt. Quinn and Roberds (2015) liken the start of this crisis in Amsterdam in 1763 to the Lehman failure of 2008, as it began with the failure of a large banking house. Quinn and Roberds (2015) and Schnabel and Shin (2004) point out the similarities between that crisis and the financial crisis of 2007-2008.…”
Section: )mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…After the failure of a large banking house in August 1763, there were runs on merchant banks that had been financing themselves with short-term debt. Quinn and Roberds (2015) liken the start of this crisis in Amsterdam in 1763 to the Lehman failure of 2008, as it began with the failure of a large banking house. Quinn and Roberds (2015) and Schnabel and Shin (2004) point out the similarities between that crisis and the financial crisis of 2007-2008.…”
Section: )mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Temin and Voth (2004) argue that haircuts in lending against stock during the South Sea bubble suggest that investors were "riding" the bubble. Schnabel and Shin (2004) argue that leverage cycles created contagion and falling asset prices in the Amsterdam financial crisis of 1763 (Quinn and Roberds 2012).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…There were no bank notes and the only alternative form of currency was specie (managed by small cashiers, Dehing 2012). To reduce transaction costs, large payments were usually settled through transfers between accounts in the Bank of Exchange(Quinn and Roberds 2014). Most of the Bank's original, handwritten, ledgers still exist.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For the Neapolitan banks it was a sizeable activity, and pawns represented liquid assets that could be sold off during runs (Tortora 1890, 246-49). Conversely, lending against collateral (like bullion or foreign coins) that was safe in having high intrinsic value, but illiquid in not being legal tender, was an important crisis management tool (Quinn and William Roberds 2015).…”
Section: Pawns and Reposmentioning
confidence: 99%