2015
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2710191
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Repeated Lobbying by Commercial Lobbyists and Special Interests

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1

Citation Types

1
10
0

Year Published

2017
2017
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
4
1

Relationship

2
3

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 8 publications
(11 citation statements)
references
References 54 publications
1
10
0
Order By: Relevance
“…This case is similar to Groll and Ellis (, ) where by assumption all political access would be allocated to commercial lobbyists. There only commercial lobbyists engage in observable lobbying efforts and guaranteed donations.…”
supporting
confidence: 58%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…This case is similar to Groll and Ellis (, ) where by assumption all political access would be allocated to commercial lobbyists. There only commercial lobbyists engage in observable lobbying efforts and guaranteed donations.…”
supporting
confidence: 58%
“…This differs from Groll and Ellis (, ) where commercial lobbyists crowd out citizens and are the only ones who gain political access. Their setting allows solving the system of equilibrium equations with its recursive structure.…”
mentioning
confidence: 72%
“…Congressional staff members play a vital role in policymaking in Congress (Salisbury and Shepsle 1981; Loomis 1988; Romzek and Utter 1997). Because of the significant increase in congressional workloads (Curry 2015) and perpetual need for fundraising and campaigning during congressional sessions (Lee 2016), members’ time for policymaking has become more scarce (Groll and Ellis 2017). Despite these challenges, the number of congressional staffers has been declining since the early 1990s.…”
Section: Congressional Staff and Their Career Concernsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Congressional staffers, despite being influential and having some degree of autonomy in their activities (Loomis 1988; Romzek and Utter 1997; Whiteman 1995), are not free agents. Although it is true that most individual member’s attention to policymaking has declined as a result of the electoral environment and other factors (Curry 2015; Groll and Ellis 2017; Lee 2016), which has increased staffers’ ability to engage in entrepreneurial behavior and affect policymaking (Montgomery and Nyhan 2017), members’ reelection incentives certainly increase their interest in assuring that policy appearing to give favors to a specific interest group or a lobbying firm is not pursued in their name.…”
Section: Congressional Staff and Their Career Concernsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…One of our model’s extensions highlights that if an interest group has to bear the cost of both information and policy implementation, then the lobby’s optimal strategy is to provide transfers to the policymaker in stages and not commit all resources up front as is common in costly access models (Austen-Smith 1995, 1998; Lohmann 1995; Cotton 2009, 2012). 10 We also illustrate how informational lobbying and legislative subsidies arise endogenously and can be either substitutes (Bennedsen and Feldmann 2006; Dahm and Porteiro 2008a, 2008b, Groll and Ellis 2014, 2017), complements (Austen-Smith 1995, 1998; Lohmann 1995; Cotton 2009, 2012), or independent.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%