2016
DOI: 10.1016/j.jebo.2016.06.005
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

“Relative concerns for consumption at the top”: An intertemporal analysis for the UK

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
4

Citation Types

1
4
0

Year Published

2017
2017
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
9

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 13 publications
(5 citation statements)
references
References 62 publications
(86 reference statements)
1
4
0
Order By: Relevance
“… These results are consistent with recent work by Quintana‐Domeque and Wohlfart () that using UK household data on food consumption find no evidence of relative concerns. …”
supporting
confidence: 92%
“… These results are consistent with recent work by Quintana‐Domeque and Wohlfart () that using UK household data on food consumption find no evidence of relative concerns. …”
supporting
confidence: 92%
“…Consistent with previous empirical and theoretical findings, the model suggests that increases in the mean income and reductions in inequality foster the competition for status by raising the cost of access to the reference group and increasing the mass of people who wants to stay with or join the relevant reference group. On one side, the effect of increases in the mean income captures the idea that the concerns for relative position become increasingly relevant as incomes rise so that social status, as a luxury good, becomes relatively more important with economic growth and/or in already rich countries (Clark et al, 2008; Heffetz & Frank, 2011; Quintana‐Domeque & Wohlfart, 2016). On the other side, greater equality stimulates the competition for status because it provides people stronger incentives to differentiate themselves (Hopkins & Kornienko, 2006; Jin et al, 2011; Quintana‐Domeque & Wohlfart, 2016).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…On one side, the effect of increases in the mean income captures the idea that the concerns for relative position become increasingly relevant as incomes rise so that social status, as a luxury good, becomes relatively more important with economic growth and/or in already rich countries (Clark et al, 2008; Heffetz & Frank, 2011; Quintana‐Domeque & Wohlfart, 2016). On the other side, greater equality stimulates the competition for status because it provides people stronger incentives to differentiate themselves (Hopkins & Kornienko, 2006; Jin et al, 2011; Quintana‐Domeque & Wohlfart, 2016). Overall, as the competition for status strengthens, a larger mass of individuals spends an increasing share of their budget in the consumption of the social participation good to reach the benchmark level of the reference group.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…An assumption made in both theoretical and empirical writings that have incorporated relative deprivation is that comparisons with others who are positioned to the right of the individual in the income distribution count equally: the income excesses of those who are close by and the income excesses of those who are farther away are accorded equal importance. However recent evidence (Obloj and Zenger, 2015;Quintana-Domeque and Wohlfart, 2016) indicates that people attach different importance to changes in incomes of individuals who are farther away in the income distribution than to changes in incomes of adjacent individuals.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%