2003
DOI: 10.1016/s1094-2025(03)00016-4
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Recursive utility, endogenous growth, and the welfare cost of volatility

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
2
1

Citation Types

1
75
0

Year Published

2009
2009
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
6
1
1

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 85 publications
(76 citation statements)
references
References 9 publications
1
75
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Ramey and Ramey (1993) explore this mechanism in a model where firms have to pre-commit to a specific technology before starting production. Stabilization may also increase welfare through its effect on capital accumulation (Matheron and Maury (2000), Epaulard and Pommeret (2003) and Barlevy (2004)). Finally, a very recent paper by Jung and Kuester (2008) emphasizes the non-linear relation between unemployment and the job finding rate.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Ramey and Ramey (1993) explore this mechanism in a model where firms have to pre-commit to a specific technology before starting production. Stabilization may also increase welfare through its effect on capital accumulation (Matheron and Maury (2000), Epaulard and Pommeret (2003) and Barlevy (2004)). Finally, a very recent paper by Jung and Kuester (2008) emphasizes the non-linear relation between unemployment and the job finding rate.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…First of all, such a specification suggests the existence of a complex relationship between the inverse of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution and population growth; very little is known on the nature of such an interaction, thus further analysis is needed in order to shed some light on the reciprocal implications between the elasticity of intertemporal substitution and demographic change. Moreover, the results derived in such a framework suggest that Edweworth's conjecture may hold only in the empirically less plausible case in which the inverse of the intertemporal elasticity of subsitution is smaller than one; such a conclusion is likely to be due to the fact that we cannot distinguish between the relative risk aversion and the intertemporal elasticity of substitution coefficients, thus it might be worthwhile to consider a recursive utility formulation as in Epaulard and Pommeret (2003) in order to allow for such a differentiation. Finally, our model's specification is extremely simplistic, thus it is natural to wonder whether and how our results would differ in a more complex setup, as a multi-sector model; specifically, extending the analysis in order to consider a two sector model driven by human capital accumulation as in Robertson (2002) or an endogenous R&D model as in Bucci (2008) would allow to further clarify the mutual relationship between growth, (human) capital accumulation, demography and uncertainty.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The figure shows that for any value of θ < 1, there exists a range of values for σ confirming Edgeworth's hypothesis; however, in order to ensure this, the variance of population change should be not too small. By changing the value of n it is possible to show that this conclusion is robust: in order for the Millian principle to imply a better economic performance than the Benthamite criterion, the variance parameter has to be large enough 9 .…”
Section: Exogenous Population Growthmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Gourio,2012) and that volatility in general and such risks in particular are associated with welfare losses (see e.g. Barro, 2009 or Epaulard and Pommeret, 2003).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%