2017
DOI: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2017.04.001
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Rags and Riches: Relative Prices, Non-Homothetic Preferences, and Inequality in India

Abstract: It is well known that consumption patterns change with income. Relative price changes would therefore affect rich and poor consumers differently. Yet, the standard price indices are not income-specific, and hence, they cannot account for such differences. In this paper, we study consumption inequality in India, while fully allowing for non-homotheticity. We show that the relative price changes during most of the period from 1993 to 2012 were pro-poor, in the sense that they favored the poor relative to the ric… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

0
4
1

Year Published

2019
2019
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
6
1

Relationship

1
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 10 publications
(6 citation statements)
references
References 37 publications
0
4
1
Order By: Relevance
“…This finding contrasts starkly with the changes in real income calculated using food and fuel Paasche and Lespeyres indices which slightly magnify the already substantial convergence seen in nominal incomes. This result also stands in contrast to Almås and Kjelsrud (2017) who estimate non-homothetic price indices using a Quadratic AIDS demand system that does not impose quasi-separability but requires well-measured price changes for the full consumption basket to implement. 38 They find that inflation was pro-poor over the period 1993-2005. Why are our price index estimates lower for richer households?…”
Section: Changes In Indian Price Indices and Welfare Over Timecontrasting
confidence: 56%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…This finding contrasts starkly with the changes in real income calculated using food and fuel Paasche and Lespeyres indices which slightly magnify the already substantial convergence seen in nominal incomes. This result also stands in contrast to Almås and Kjelsrud (2017) who estimate non-homothetic price indices using a Quadratic AIDS demand system that does not impose quasi-separability but requires well-measured price changes for the full consumption basket to implement. 38 They find that inflation was pro-poor over the period 1993-2005. Why are our price index estimates lower for richer households?…”
Section: Changes In Indian Price Indices and Welfare Over Timecontrasting
confidence: 56%
“…In particular, the rich spent a large and increasing share of their budget on durables such as manufactures and on services. 39 These are exactly the categories for which unobserved quality differences make price data unreliable and so are omitted in Deaton's CPI approach which only covers well-measured food and fuels, and are crudely captured, if at all, by the government non-food CPI in the Almås and Kjelsrud (2017) approach. As touched upon in the introduction, lower inflation in these specific categories is consistent with the fact that the Indian trade 38 See footnote 6 for a detailed description of how Almås and Kjelsrud (2017) the ratio of the Indian food and nonfood CPI to navigate the lack of well-measured price data for categories beyond food and fuels.…”
Section: Changes In Indian Price Indices and Welfare Over Timementioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…The nationally representative consumer expenditure survey of 2004-05 is used which samples about 120,000 households across rural and urban India. Following Almås and Kjelsrud (2017), we classify all expenditure into 11 categories. Tables 1 and 2 list these categories and also display across the urban and rural sectors, the mean budget shares as well measures of dispersionboth evaluated by the democratic density.…”
Section: Indiamentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For simplicity, I do not distinguish between different types of publicly provided goods and services. In the empirical exercise, however, I use measures of availability for several types of government facilities.12 Price levels are similarly likely to change with income because people's consumption patterns typically change, meaning that there is no such thing as a unique cost of living relevant for all income groups(Muellbauer, 1974;Pendakur, 2002;Almås and Kjelsrud, 2017).C 2022 The Author. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd on behalf of Föreningen för utgivande av the SJE.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%