1974
DOI: 10.1016/0047-2727(74)90028-0
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Public goods, efficiency, and regional fiscal equalization

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

2
103
0
2

Year Published

1998
1998
2015
2015

Publication Types

Select...
6
2

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 261 publications
(108 citation statements)
references
References 1 publication
2
103
0
2
Order By: Relevance
“…Using the price and variety distortions for the differentiated good, we can rewrite ( 57 ) to obtain the extension of Harberger's excess burden to include the variety distortion. Because this is for the entire economy, we have to divide this by the number of cities to obtain the condition that corresponds to Flatters et al (1974): If the initial allocation, where 0  A , has the optimal city size, then 0 /  dN dA , which immediately yields the corollary.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Using the price and variety distortions for the differentiated good, we can rewrite ( 57 ) to obtain the extension of Harberger's excess burden to include the variety distortion. Because this is for the entire economy, we have to divide this by the number of cities to obtain the condition that corresponds to Flatters et al (1974): If the initial allocation, where 0  A , has the optimal city size, then 0 /  dN dA , which immediately yields the corollary.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In a symmetric case where all cities have the same allocation, this is equivalent to finding the optimal size of a city. Flatters et al (1974) considered the latter problem to obtain the first-best HGT for local public goods (called the 'golden rule' there). Because the number of cities satisfies N N n /  , we can re-express our results in terms of the optimal size of a single city by maximizing the Allais surplus ( 15 ) with respect to the population of a city:…”
Section: Proposition 2 (Optimal Number Of Cities)mentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…The incentive equivalence result applied mainly to the efficiency of regional fiscal decision-making when regions provide local public goods for which there is no spillover. However, even if fiscal choices are efficient, migration can be inefficient, as shown by Buchanan and Goetz (1972) and Flatters, Henderson and Mieszkowski (1974). One important rationale for federal equalization transfers is to correct this inefficiency of migration.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, allowing such a coalitional deviation of consumers does not fit very well with Tiebout's original tale: unlike Samuelson's pure public goods case, the market mechanism can achieve efficient allocations in equilibria even if jurisdictions cannot observe each consumer's preferences. 14 In this paper, instead of assuming entrepreneurial consumers, we assume entrepreneurial jurisdiction managers. We will use a version of the well-known equilibrium concept defined for markets with asymmetric information (adverse selection) by Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976).…”
Section: Type W Jurisdictionmentioning
confidence: 99%