2006
DOI: 10.1007/s11127-006-9062-8
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Public choice principles of redistricting

Abstract: Abstract. This paper uses fundamental principles of public choice, mainly the median voter theorem, to develop a simple theory of redistricting. The focus is on how closely policy outcomes correspond to majority rule. The main results are: (1) Potential policy bias in favor of nonmajority groups is structurally linked to the number of legislative seats and the population, and the structure of most states puts them very close to the theoretically maximum bias. (2) Random districting, which might seem like the e… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

2
23
0
2

Year Published

2009
2009
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

1
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 47 publications
(27 citation statements)
references
References 29 publications
(16 reference statements)
2
23
0
2
Order By: Relevance
“…For example, if legislators draw lines to increase the number of seats held by their party, they may actually create numerous competitive districts, each with a small margin in their favor (Gelman and King, 1994). Even if districts are competitive so that each legislator ends up representing the district's median voter, district lines can be gerrymandered so that the median legislator is not congruent with the median voter in the population, and even random redistricting will result in noncongruent policies (Gilligan and Matsusaka, 2006). • Ballot access.…”
Section: Determinants Of Congruence: Election Institutionsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For example, if legislators draw lines to increase the number of seats held by their party, they may actually create numerous competitive districts, each with a small margin in their favor (Gelman and King, 1994). Even if districts are competitive so that each legislator ends up representing the district's median voter, district lines can be gerrymandered so that the median legislator is not congruent with the median voter in the population, and even random redistricting will result in noncongruent policies (Gilligan and Matsusaka, 2006). • Ballot access.…”
Section: Determinants Of Congruence: Election Institutionsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…That is, ρ(H) is the unique distribution such that ρ(H)(x) = 1 − H(−x) at every continuity point of ρ(H). 6 If G is the segregation constraint for party 2 then ρ(G) is the translation of G that makes G comparable to F , the segregation constraint of party 1. If ρ(G) = F then both parties face the same segregation constraint.…”
Section: An Example With No Local Uncertaintymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Bradbury and Crain (2001) present empirical evidence of differences in the strength of the Law of 1/n between unicameral and bicameral legislatures. Gilligan and Matsusaka (2006) argue that the relationship between legislature size and spending may in fact be due to gerrymandering. Ansolabehere, Snyder Jr., and Ting (2003) model bicameral legislatures in a bargaining framework and considers the possibility of forming minimum winning coalitions among house representatives alone; Chen and Malhotra (2007) use a similar game theoretic approach and shows that the ratio of chamber sizes is the more relevant variable (and is negatively related to spending), while Maldonado (2013) uses international data to find a linear relationship between chamber size and spending in countries with unicameral legislatures and a nonlinear relationship in those with bicameral legislatures.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%