2018
DOI: 10.1007/978-3-030-04612-5_24
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Prophet Inequalities vs. Approximating Optimum Online

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
4
1

Citation Types

0
9
0

Year Published

2019
2019
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
3
2
2

Relationship

1
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 7 publications
(9 citation statements)
references
References 28 publications
0
9
0
Order By: Relevance
“…We next turn to the approximability of the optimal online policy, where we might hope to achieve higher approximation guarantees. For the classic prophet inequality problem, Niazadeh et al [25] show that pricing-based policies yield no better approximation of the optimal online policy than they do of the optimal offline policy. For the stationary prophet inequality problem, the same is not true; while our inapproximability result of Theorem 1.1 implies that no competitive ratio beyond 1 /2 is possible, an algorithm of [3] yields a 1− 1 /e ≈ 0.632 approximation of the optimal online policy.…”
Section: Our Contributionsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…We next turn to the approximability of the optimal online policy, where we might hope to achieve higher approximation guarantees. For the classic prophet inequality problem, Niazadeh et al [25] show that pricing-based policies yield no better approximation of the optimal online policy than they do of the optimal offline policy. For the stationary prophet inequality problem, the same is not true; while our inapproximability result of Theorem 1.1 implies that no competitive ratio beyond 1 /2 is possible, an algorithm of [3] yields a 1− 1 /e ≈ 0.632 approximation of the optimal online policy.…”
Section: Our Contributionsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The classic single-item prophet inequality problem has been generalized to selling more complicated combinatorical structures, including, e.g., multiple items [1,7,18], knapsacks [12,16], matroids and their intersections [4,8,12,16,20], matchings [12,14,15,16,17], and arbitrary downward-closed families [27]. Most of this work has focused on approximating the offline optimum algorithm, with recent work also studying the (in)approximability of the optimal online algorithm by poly-time algorithms [2,26] and particularly by posted-price policies [25]. Much of the interest in prophet inequality problems, and specifically pricing-based policies, has been fueled by their implication of truthful mechanisms which approximately maximize social welfare and revenue, first observed in [8] (see the surveys [10,19,23], and [11] for the "opposite" direction).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…That is, rather than using the standard prophet benchmark, we use the arguably more realistic benchmark of the best order-aware online algorithm. This is part of a growing interest in alternative benchmarks to the prophet benchmark Kessel et al [2021], Niazadeh et al [2018], Papadimitriou et al [2021]. For example, Niazadeh et al [2018] quantify the loss due to single-threshold algorithms by the worst-case ratio between the best single-threshold algorithm and the best general online algorithm (single-threshold or not), both under a known order, and show that this 1/2 ratio is tight.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This is part of a growing interest in alternative benchmarks to the prophet benchmark Kessel et al [2021], Niazadeh et al [2018], Papadimitriou et al [2021]. For example, Niazadeh et al [2018] quantify the loss due to single-threshold algorithms by the worst-case ratio between the best single-threshold algorithm and the best general online algorithm (single-threshold or not), both under a known order, and show that this 1/2 ratio is tight. As another example, Papadimitriou et al [2021] consider the problem of online matching in bipartite graphs.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation