2002
DOI: 10.1007/s712-002-8221-x
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Private and Public Information in Self-fulfilling Currency Crises

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1

Citation Types

8
81
1

Year Published

2002
2002
2015
2015

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

1
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 69 publications
(91 citation statements)
references
References 11 publications
(15 reference statements)
8
81
1
Order By: Relevance
“…2 See Morris and Shin (1999), Daníelson et al (2001), Heinemann and Illing (2002), Hellwig (2002), Metz (2002), and Prati and Sbracia (2002). (1995), and Kübler and Weizsäcker (2004) show that subjects' behavior is more consistent with finite levels of beliefs over beliefs than with theoretical predictions from common knowledge.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…2 See Morris and Shin (1999), Daníelson et al (2001), Heinemann and Illing (2002), Hellwig (2002), Metz (2002), and Prati and Sbracia (2002). (1995), and Kübler and Weizsäcker (2004) show that subjects' behavior is more consistent with finite levels of beliefs over beliefs than with theoretical predictions from common knowledge.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Referring to the results of the literature on "global games" 15 , it has been shown that investors' behavior is predictable, i.e. they choose a uniquely optimal strategy even for intermediate fundamental values, if they possess very precise private information, relative to the precision of publicly-available information (Morris and Shin (2002);Metz (2002)). In this respect, public information is defined as pieces of information that are known to all investors and that are known to be known to all investors and so forth.…”
Section: Liquiditymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Game theory relying on Nash equilibria typically assumes away this type of uncertainty (Hirshleifer and Riley, 1992). Whereas the model by Obstfeld (1994Obstfeld ( , 1996 includes neither fundamental nor behavioural uncertainty due to the assumption of complete and common information, the model by Morris and Shin (1998) Obstfeld (1994,1996) Sbracia and Zaghini (2001 Behavioural Uncertainty Heinemann and Illing (2002) Morris and Shin (1998) Metz (2002Metz ( , 2003a Heinemann and Metz (2002) A study by Sbracia and Zaghini (2001) analyses the case where information about fundamentals is public, but not completely precise, so that uncertainty about traders' behaviour is resolved, since all traders possess the same 'common' information, while fundamental uncertainty still prevails. Such situation might be interpreted as market participants holding the same view on publicly disseminated information.…”
Section: Privacy or Publicity -Who Drives The Wheel?mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In order to give advice to policy makers searching for the optimal design of information policy, Metz (2002Metz ( , 2003a and Heinemann and Metz (2002) examined more closely the simultaneous interrelation of private and public information on foreign exchange markets and their influence on traders' behaviour when characterized by strategic complementarities. 1 The studies found that the impact of the precision of information on traders' behaviour is contingent on two factors.…”
Section: Privacy or Publicity -Who Drives The Wheel?mentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation