2008
DOI: 10.21034/sr.404
|View full text |Cite
Preprint
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

Abstract: International relative prices across industrialized countries show large and systematic deviations from relative purchasing power parity. We embed a model of imperfect competition and variable markups in a quantitative model of international trade. We find that when our model is parameterized to match salient features of the data on international trade and market structure in the US, it can reproduce deviations from relative purchasing power parity similar to those observed in the data because firms choose to … Show more

Help me understand this report
View published versions

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

15
263
2

Year Published

2009
2009
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
5
2
1

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 126 publications
(280 citation statements)
references
References 29 publications
15
263
2
Order By: Relevance
“…Importantly, we show that our model with product replacements maps directly into standard general equilibrium models that abstract from product replacements. 5 Our adjusted pass-through estimates line up well with the implications of leading general equilibrium models such as Corsetti and Dedola (2005), Atkeson and Burstein (2008) and Drozd and Nosal (2011), which imply longrun pass-through between 0.7 and 0.9. 6 Our adjustment can also be applied to measures of passthrough based on the bilateral exchange rate.…”
Section: Introductionsupporting
confidence: 66%
“…Importantly, we show that our model with product replacements maps directly into standard general equilibrium models that abstract from product replacements. 5 Our adjusted pass-through estimates line up well with the implications of leading general equilibrium models such as Corsetti and Dedola (2005), Atkeson and Burstein (2008) and Drozd and Nosal (2011), which imply longrun pass-through between 0.7 and 0.9. 6 Our adjustment can also be applied to measures of passthrough based on the bilateral exchange rate.…”
Section: Introductionsupporting
confidence: 66%
“…8 For our purposes, scanner data such as those used by Bai and Stumpner (2018) suffer from certain drawbacks: (a) the sample covers consumer packaged goods (about 10% of total expenditures) and is not representative of several important Second, our estimates of the benefits of trade with China for consumers through lower prices complement a large literature that has documented adverse effects for employment (e.g., Autor et al (2013), Autor et al (2014), Pierce and Schott (2016a) and Bloom et al (2019)), mortality (Pierce and Schott (2016b)), marriage, fertility and children's living circumstances (Autor et al (2018)), domestic innovation and investment and Autor et al (2019)), and political polarization (Autor et al (2016)). Third, by showing importance of the "pro-competitive effects of trade" to explain the observed price response, our paper is part of a large literature that has estimated the empirical relationship between international trade and markups (e.g., Levinsohn (1993), Krishna and Mitra (1998), Nakamura and Zerom (2010), Feenstra and Weinstein (2017), Arkolakis et al (2018), Auer et al (2018) and Amiti et al (2018b)) and that has examined the extent to which opening up to trade may reduce markup distortions (e.g., Brander and Krugman (1983), Atkeson and Burstein (2008), Epifani and Gancia (2011), Edmond et al (2015), Feenstra (2018), and Impullitti and Licandro (2018)). Finally, our findings speak to a growing literature on the distributional effects of trade via the expenditure channel (e.g., Porto (2006) and He (2018), and the aforementioned studies).…”
Section: Indistinguishablementioning
confidence: 99%
“…With constant markups, the markup is inelastic and we obtain that Γ i j = Γ −i j = 0. With oligopolistic competition (e.g., Krugman (1979) and Atkeson and Burstein (2008)), Γ i and Γ −i are increasing in the firm's market share. Under relatively mild assumptions about the demand system, Amiti et al (2018b) show that Γ i j = Γ −i j .…”
Section: Ivd the Role Of Changes In Markupsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This result gains further importance in light of the overwhelming empirical evidence in support of the existence of market segmentation across countries (see, for example, Atkeson and Burstein [] and Knetter [, ] for evidence of price discrimination by exporting firms across different destination countries) . Moreover, the majority of cross‐border mergers during the last two decades have been realized within service industries such as financial services, where market segmentation and price discrimination prevail (see Section VI for further details).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 93%
“…Atkeson and Burstein [] use aggregate price data from exporting manufacturing firms in the U.S., the U.K., Japan, Germany, France, Italy and Canada for the period 1985–2006. Knetter [, ] uses the annual value and quantity of exports to selected destination countries for a number of seven‐digit industries in four source countries: the U.S., the U.K., Japan, and Germany, for the period 1975–1987.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%