Proceedings of the Fifteenth ACM Conference on Economics and Computation 2014
DOI: 10.1145/2600057.2602878
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Price of anarchy for auction revenue

Abstract: This paper develops tools for welfare and revenue analyses of Bayes-Nash equilibria in asymmetric auctions with single-dimensional agents. We employ these tools to derive approximation results for social welfare and revenue. Our approach separates the smoothness framework of [e.g., Syrgkanis and Tardos, 2013] into two distinct parts, isolating the analysis common to any auction from the analysis specific to a given auction. The first part relates a bidder's contribution to welfare in equilibrium to their contr… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
50
0

Year Published

2015
2015
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
4
3
1

Relationship

1
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 39 publications
(51 citation statements)
references
References 36 publications
(100 reference statements)
1
50
0
Order By: Relevance
“…This and similar properties have been used in previous works to upper-bound the Price of Anarchy by O(γ) (see, e.g., [Lucier and Borodin 2010;Syrgkanis and Tardos 2013;Babaioff et al 2014;Hartline et al 2014]). Our main technical achievement is to show that the above condition and a suitable generalization to randomized mechanisms yields matching upper and lower bounds.…”
Section: Our Resultsmentioning
confidence: 71%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…This and similar properties have been used in previous works to upper-bound the Price of Anarchy by O(γ) (see, e.g., [Lucier and Borodin 2010;Syrgkanis and Tardos 2013;Babaioff et al 2014;Hartline et al 2014]). Our main technical achievement is to show that the above condition and a suitable generalization to randomized mechanisms yields matching upper and lower bounds.…”
Section: Our Resultsmentioning
confidence: 71%
“…Also relevant as a precursor and parallel literature to our work is work that analyzes the Price of Anarchy of simple mechanisms, such as [Christodoulou et al 2008;Bhawalkar and Roughgarden 2011;Feldman et al 2013], work that extends the smoothness concept so that it also yields revenue guarantees [Hartline et al 2014], and work that identifies barriers to near-optimal equilibria [Roughgarden 2014]. The first line of work differs from ours as it considers the performance of simple mechanisms for specific problems.…”
Section: Related Workmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Our approach is an empirical analogue of the smoothness approach on quantifying the worst-case inefficiency in games [Roughgarden 2009;Syrgkanis and Tardos 2013;Hartline et al 2014] and therefore inherits several robustness properties of smoothness. For instance, the lower bound on the efficiency that is derived via our method holds regardless of whether the data that we observe are the product of a Bayes-Nash equilibrium where the player valuations are stochastic, or whether they are the product of a learning process employed by an advertiser with a fixed valuation.…”
Section: Data-driven Robust Efficiency Guaranteesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The smoothness approach of [Syrgkanis and Tardos 2013] and its refinement for single-parameter mechanism design environments, via the revenue and value covering formulation of [Hartline et al 2014] is based on the following argument: at any outcome of the game that satisfies a best-response or approximate best-response property either the player is getting high utility and hence high allocation probability, or the payment that he needs to make in order to achieve a high allocation probability given the competition must be high. The latter quantity is typically referred to as the threshold payment.…”
Section: Data-driven Robust Efficiency Guaranteesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, in the most commonly studied setting with independently distributed values over a single good, there has been a persistent gap between this welfare guarantee and the worst known example of Hartline et al (2014), in which the social welfare is a .869-fraction of the optimal social welfare. Despite the prevalence of the first-price auction format, the salience of the independent values assumption, and the ubiquity of the techniques used to prove the existing e−1 e bound, it was not clear whether this bound was tight in the independent values setting.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%