2018
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3125213
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Persistent Effects of Autonomous Demand Expansions

Abstract: The prevailing wisdom that aggregate demand shocks determine short-run cyclical fluctuations around a supply-determined equilibrium growth rate and an associated equilibrium unemployment rate (or NAIRU) has been called into question by various strands of literature over the last few decades. Specifically, a recently revived literature on hysteresis finds significant persistence in the effects of negative aggregate demand shocks (e.g.

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

2
12
0
1

Year Published

2019
2019
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
6

Relationship

0
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 15 publications
(15 citation statements)
references
References 76 publications
2
12
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…Higher wage growth may raise inflation considerably less than expected, in other words, because the rate of potential growth goes up in response to the increases in productivity, demand and actual output induced by the extra wage growth (see Figure 2; Storm and Naastepad 2012;Storm 2018;Girardi et al 2018;Fontanari et al 2019). If so, the reverse holds true as well: sluggish business investment in the U.S. has been a key factor behind the stagnation of TFP growth and has also been responsible for propagating hysteresis-like adverse consequences for TFP and potential output after 2008 (see Hall 2014;Ollivaud et al 2016;Fazzari et al 2017;Cynamon and Fazzari 2017;Girardi et al 2018). This conclusion only becomes stronger once we acknowledge the 'cumulative causation' at work: sluggish investment weakens aggregate demand and this, in turn, weakens accumulation through the 'accelerator effect' -which was Nicholas Kaldor's argument -as well as real wage growth, which reduces the rate of labor-saving technological progress (as argued here).…”
Section: Wage Growth As a Determinant Of Productivity Growthmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 4 more Smart Citations
“…Higher wage growth may raise inflation considerably less than expected, in other words, because the rate of potential growth goes up in response to the increases in productivity, demand and actual output induced by the extra wage growth (see Figure 2; Storm and Naastepad 2012;Storm 2018;Girardi et al 2018;Fontanari et al 2019). If so, the reverse holds true as well: sluggish business investment in the U.S. has been a key factor behind the stagnation of TFP growth and has also been responsible for propagating hysteresis-like adverse consequences for TFP and potential output after 2008 (see Hall 2014;Ollivaud et al 2016;Fazzari et al 2017;Cynamon and Fazzari 2017;Girardi et al 2018). This conclusion only becomes stronger once we acknowledge the 'cumulative causation' at work: sluggish investment weakens aggregate demand and this, in turn, weakens accumulation through the 'accelerator effect' -which was Nicholas Kaldor's argument -as well as real wage growth, which reduces the rate of labor-saving technological progress (as argued here).…”
Section: Wage Growth As a Determinant Of Productivity Growthmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, the problem with this simple 'intuition' is that it is wrong. There are sound theoretical reasons, and there is robust empirical evidence, to blame (a substantial part of) the long-run decline in productivity growth on stalling demand growth (Storm 2017;Girardi, Paternesi Meloni and Stirati 2018;Fontanari et al 2019). This goes against a deeprooted theoretical belief system which maintains that long-run trend growth, which is argued to be determined by the supply-side factors 'technology' and 'demography', can be completely separated from short-run fluctuations of actual growth around this trend, which are held to be due to changes in demand.…”
Section: Bringing Demand In From the Coldmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 3 more Smart Citations