2011
DOI: 10.1080/13533312.2011.598317
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Partnering for Troop Supply

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
3
0

Year Published

2015
2015
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
2

Relationship

0
2

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 2 publications
(3 citation statements)
references
References 0 publications
0
3
0
Order By: Relevance
“…On the resource front, in particular, a concurrent rise in the number of peacekeepers deployed globally (Providing for Peacekeeping, no date(a)) and in the fee that the UN was willing to pay to governments for each troop deployed to a UN mission (Coleman and Nyblade, 2018: 728) meant that leaders in (low-income) countries soon found that they could ‘profit’ from contributing to peacekeeping (see Gaibulloev et al, 2015). This is because payments for peacekeepers were (and still are) typically transferred directly to ministries or governments’ central coffers (Coleman, 2014: 28), and so governing elites that paid their own troops less than the rate of UN reimbursement (then around $1000 per troop, per month) stood to earn rent from supplying peacekeepers to the UN’s increasingly large missions (Bobrow and Boyer, 1997; see also Daniel, 2011: 541).…”
Section: Theoretical Framework: Benefits Costs and Regime-specific Cmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…On the resource front, in particular, a concurrent rise in the number of peacekeepers deployed globally (Providing for Peacekeeping, no date(a)) and in the fee that the UN was willing to pay to governments for each troop deployed to a UN mission (Coleman and Nyblade, 2018: 728) meant that leaders in (low-income) countries soon found that they could ‘profit’ from contributing to peacekeeping (see Gaibulloev et al, 2015). This is because payments for peacekeepers were (and still are) typically transferred directly to ministries or governments’ central coffers (Coleman, 2014: 28), and so governing elites that paid their own troops less than the rate of UN reimbursement (then around $1000 per troop, per month) stood to earn rent from supplying peacekeepers to the UN’s increasingly large missions (Bobrow and Boyer, 1997; see also Daniel, 2011: 541).…”
Section: Theoretical Framework: Benefits Costs and Regime-specific Cmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…First, I find that democracies are no more likely to participate in any given UN peacekeeping mission than are non-democracies (see Lebovic, 2004). Daniel (2011) suggests that the UN should draw more heavily from democracies interested in promoting a Western agenda globally when trying to fulfill its mandated troop levels, and Bellamy & Williams (2013) note that it is important for these Western democracies to contribute, as they have better military capabilities to assist the UN. However, my results indicate that democratic interests are similar to those of non-democracies: they are not likely to become involved in peacekeeping unless the crisis threatens them directly.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Participation in peacekeeping provides democracies the means to both respond to domestic pressures to provide humanitarian relief abroad and help further liberal norms of conflict resolution in other countries (e.g. Daniel, 2011; Lebovic, 2004; Marten, 2004). In this manner, peacekeeping allows democracies to further their interests and promote the status quo from which they benefit (Neack, 1995).…”
Section: Existing Scholarshipmentioning
confidence: 99%