2014
DOI: 10.1037/a0035128
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Options as information: Rational reversals of evaluation and preference.

Abstract: This article develops a rational analysis of an important class of apparent preference reversals-jointseparate reversals traditionally explained by the evaluability hypothesis. The "options-as-information" model considers a hypothetical rational actor with limited knowledge about the market distribution of a stimulus attribute. The actor's evaluations are formed via a 2-stage process-an inferential stage in which beliefs are updated on the basis of the sample of options received, followed by an assessment stag… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1

Citation Types

2
33
0

Year Published

2017
2017
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
5

Relationship

1
4

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 28 publications
(35 citation statements)
references
References 62 publications
(102 reference statements)
2
33
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Modelers drew very different inferences across joint and separate evaluation conditions, and these different inferences were sufficient to reproduce the JSR in recipients, all of whom evaluated only a single option. These results provided support for an “options‐as‐information” model, according to which JSRs occur not because of different attribute weighting in different “evaluation modes” (joint vs. separate) but because of the different inferences that are drawn from different option samples (Sher & McKenzie, ). Sample‐based inference likely also contributes to the asymmetric dominance effect (Prelec, Wernerfelt, & Zettelmeyer, ; Sher, Müller‐Trede, & McKenzie, ) and can lead to intransitive behavior in multi‐attribute choice (Müller‐Trede, Sher, & McKenzie, ).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 75%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Modelers drew very different inferences across joint and separate evaluation conditions, and these different inferences were sufficient to reproduce the JSR in recipients, all of whom evaluated only a single option. These results provided support for an “options‐as‐information” model, according to which JSRs occur not because of different attribute weighting in different “evaluation modes” (joint vs. separate) but because of the different inferences that are drawn from different option samples (Sher & McKenzie, ). Sample‐based inference likely also contributes to the asymmetric dominance effect (Prelec, Wernerfelt, & Zettelmeyer, ; Sher, Müller‐Trede, & McKenzie, ) and can lead to intransitive behavior in multi‐attribute choice (Müller‐Trede, Sher, & McKenzie, ).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 75%
“…JSRs occur when an option that is superior on a difficult‐to‐evaluate attribute receives high ratings when judged jointly with the alternative option and low ratings when judged in isolation (Hsee, ). In a study resembling Experiment 1, Sher and McKenzie () presented modeler participants two options either separately or jointly and then asked them to estimate the mean and range of the difficult‐to‐evaluate attribute. Modelers drew very different inferences across joint and separate evaluation conditions, and these different inferences were sufficient to reproduce the JSR in recipients, all of whom evaluated only a single option.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…We note that, in addition to ALT, DbS, and RFT, Sher and McKenzie (; see also Muller‐Trede, Sher, & McKenzie, ) have proposed that the location of marketplace options with respect to particular attributes (e.g., annual pension income) is relevant to the evaluation of that scale in their “options‐as‐information” model. Decision makers who are somewhat uninformed as to what constitutes a “good” pension income will update their distribution of marketplace options with those presented in a particular choice situation (or prior to it in our case).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 97%
“…In fact, there is some evidence that would support this explanation. Sher and McKenzie (2014) showed one group of subjects (group 1) objects A and B and they were asked to provide their WTP only for object A. They also presented objects A and B to another group (group 2), but they were asked about their WTP only for object B.…”
Section: Imprecision or Stochastic Preferencesmentioning
confidence: 99%