2013
DOI: 10.1016/j.jmacro.2013.03.001
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Optimal tax policy under habit formation and capital utilization

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
4

Citation Types

0
8
0

Year Published

2014
2014
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

2
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 7 publications
(8 citation statements)
references
References 24 publications
0
8
0
Order By: Relevance
“…First, it reconciles two distinct approaches in the literature on habit formation; the aggregate habit approach (e.g. Abel, 1990;Monteiro et al, 2013) which considers only a single aggregate consumption good and the corresponding habit; and the 'deep' habits approach by Ravn et al (2006;, which allows for habit formation at the level of many specific goods. Second, existing specifications of good-specific habit formation (e.g.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 94%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…First, it reconciles two distinct approaches in the literature on habit formation; the aggregate habit approach (e.g. Abel, 1990;Monteiro et al, 2013) which considers only a single aggregate consumption good and the corresponding habit; and the 'deep' habits approach by Ravn et al (2006;, which allows for habit formation at the level of many specific goods. Second, existing specifications of good-specific habit formation (e.g.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 94%
“…Aronsson and JohanssonStenman (2014) find that non-internalized habits tend to increase optimal marginal labor taxes, and have ambiguous effects on optimal capital taxes. In the context of growth, Alonso-Carrera et al (2005), Turnovsky and Monteiro (2007) and Monteiro et al (2013) characterize the income and consumption tax rates that implement the optimal path of consumption as the economy transitions to a balanced growth path. In Cremer et al's (2010) two-period model with retirement, habit formation and myopia cause overconsumption and undersaving in the first period of life.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…First, it reconciles two distinct approaches in the literature on habit formation; the aggregate habit approach (e.g. Abel, 1990;Monteiro et al, 2013) which considers only a single aggregate consumption good and the corresponding habit; and the 'deep' habits approach by Ravn et al (2006;, which allows for habit formation at the level of many specific goods. Second, existing specifications of good-specific habit formation (e.g.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 97%
“…Aronsson and Johansson-Stenman (2014) find that non-internalized habits tend to increase optimal marginal labor taxes, and have ambiguous effects on optimal capital taxes. In the context of growth, Alonso-Carrera et al ( 2005), Turnovsky and Monteiro (2007) and Monteiro et al (2013) characterize the income and consumption tax rates that implement the optimal path of consumption as the economy transitions to a balanced growth path. In Cremer et al's (2010) two-period model with retirement, habit formation and myopia cause overconsumption and undersaving in the first period of life.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…These two versions are referred to as the inward-and outward-looking versions, respectively, by Carroll et al (1997). The inward version is adopted by Carroll et al (2000), Monteiro et al (2013) following Ryder and Heal (1973), etc., while the outward version is considered by Liu and Turnovsky (2005), Turnovsky and Monteiro (2007), Wendner (2011), among others. Finally, both types of consumption reference levels are 2 Different terms for positional preferences have been used in the literature, with slightly differing meanings.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%