2019
DOI: 10.1016/j.jmateco.2019.04.007
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

One-step-ahead implementation

Abstract: In many situations, agents are involved in an allocation problem that is followed by another allocation problem whose optimal solution depends on how the former problem has been solved. In this paper, we take this dynamic structure of allocation problems as an institutional constraint. By assuming a …nite number of allocation problems, one for each period/stage, and by assuming that all agents in society are involved in each allocation problem, a dynamic mechanism is a period-by-period process. This process ge… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

0
6
0

Year Published

2019
2019
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
4
1

Relationship

2
3

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 7 publications
(6 citation statements)
references
References 34 publications
0
6
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Our sequential treatment is motivated by the theoretical work of Hayashi and Lombardi (2019), which studies what can be implemented in the multi-period setting in which allocation in the current period must be chosen and finalized, without any commitment to allocations in future periods. This handles more restricted situations than in the existing research on subgameperfect implementation (Moore and Repullo, 1988), which allows that an entire social outcome, once chosen at some stage, can be overturned at any subsequent stage.…”
Section: Related Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Our sequential treatment is motivated by the theoretical work of Hayashi and Lombardi (2019), which studies what can be implemented in the multi-period setting in which allocation in the current period must be chosen and finalized, without any commitment to allocations in future periods. This handles more restricted situations than in the existing research on subgameperfect implementation (Moore and Repullo, 1988), which allows that an entire social outcome, once chosen at some stage, can be overturned at any subsequent stage.…”
Section: Related Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%
“…First, although most studies in the subgame-perfect implementation literature allow canceling at any stage, this is not a realistic assumption in the multi-sector setting. Note that when sequential elicitation is applied for the two-sector allocation problem, a realistic specification is that the allocation for one sector is finalized in the first stage, without any commitment to allocation for the other sector to be made in the second stage, and no cancellation of the first sector allocation is allowed afterwards (Hayashi and Lombardi, 2019). This is typically the case when we must finalize housing allocation before school seats are assigned.…”
Section: Two Treatmentsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…While constrained monotonicity is necessary for constrained implementation, it is not su¢ cient. 5 We need an extra condition for the su¢ ciency result.…”
Section: A Characterization Theoremmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…See the Appendix. 5 For example, suppose that A 2 = a 2 . As we noted in Section 3, constrained monotonicity is equivalent to monotonicity when A 2 = a 2 .…”
Section: A Characterization Theoremmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…A constant SCF is trivially implementable.3 Hayashi and Lombardi (2019) also study implementation in a dynamic setup, but in any given period, the socially desirable alternative depends not only on the state, but also on the history of alternatives that have been selected in the previous periods.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%