2011
DOI: 10.1016/j.red.2010.11.001
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Oil price shocks and the optimality of monetary policy

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
4

Citation Types

2
35
1

Year Published

2012
2012
2017
2017

Publication Types

Select...
7
3

Relationship

0
10

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 80 publications
(38 citation statements)
references
References 34 publications
2
35
1
Order By: Relevance
“…In particular, in a monthly vector autoregression (VAR) model, the recursive identification that assumes no feedback from domestic macroeconomic shocks to the price of energy with the same month (see, inter alia, Blanchard andGali, 2010, andLeduc andSill, 2004, and the references contained therein) is not supported by the data. Moreover, in contrast to most of the existing literature (see, e.g., Carlstrom and Fuerst, 2006;Kormilitsina, 2011;Natal, 2012) the empirical findings suggest that oil prices should be treated as endogenous variables in dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models.…”
Section: Introductioncontrasting
confidence: 77%
“…In particular, in a monthly vector autoregression (VAR) model, the recursive identification that assumes no feedback from domestic macroeconomic shocks to the price of energy with the same month (see, inter alia, Blanchard andGali, 2010, andLeduc andSill, 2004, and the references contained therein) is not supported by the data. Moreover, in contrast to most of the existing literature (see, e.g., Carlstrom and Fuerst, 2006;Kormilitsina, 2011;Natal, 2012) the empirical findings suggest that oil prices should be treated as endogenous variables in dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models.…”
Section: Introductioncontrasting
confidence: 77%
“…3 See, for instance, Bernanke et al (1997); Barsky and Kilian (2001); Bodenstein et al (2008); Nakov and Pescatori (2010); Kormilitsina (2011);Bodenstein et al (2012);and Natal (2012). 4 The importance of time-variation in the variance of key macroeconomic aggregates has most clearly emerged from the analysis of competing explanations for the steep decline in inflation and output volatility since the mid1980s (often referred to as the Great Moderation); see, for instance, Primiceri (2005); Sims and Zha (2006).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Much of the existing analysis on the conduct of monetary policy in the face of oil price fluctuations relies on the counterfactual premise that the real price of crude oil is exogenous with respect to the U.S. economy (see, for example, Leduc and Sill, 2004;Carlstrom and Fuerst, 2006;Dhawan and Jeske, 2007;Plante, 2009a, b;Winkler, 2009;Montoro, 2010;Kormilitsina, 2011;Natal, 2012). Even those DSGE studies that have endogenized the real price of oil have made strong and unrealistic simplifying assumptions about the determination of the price of oil in global markets (see, for example, Backus and Crucini, 1998), have ignored monetary policy (see, for example, Backus and Crucini, 1998;Balke, Brown, and Yu¨cel, 2010;Bodenstein, Erceg, and Guerrieri, 2011;Nakov and Nun˜o, 2011), or have ignored the open economy aspect of the transmission of oil price shocks (see, for example, Bodenstein, Erceg, and Guerrieri, 2008;Nakov and Pescatori, 2010a, b).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%