2019
DOI: 10.1111/jmcb.12602
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Nominal GDP Targeting and the Taylor Rule on an Even Playing Field

Abstract: Some economists advocate nominal GDP targeting as an alternative to the Taylor Rule. These arguments are largely based on the idea that nominal GDP targeting would require less knowledge on the part of policymakers than a traditional Taylor Rule. In particular, a nominal GDP targeting rule would not require real‐time knowledge of the output gap. We examine the importance of this claim by amending a standard New Keynesian model to assume that the central bank has imperfect information about the output gap and t… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
20
0

Year Published

2020
2020
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

1
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 33 publications
(21 citation statements)
references
References 32 publications
1
20
0
Order By: Relevance
“…For example, using a New Keynesian model with imperfect information, Beckworth and Hendrickson (2016) show that the Fed's output gap forecasts over 1987-2007 explain only 13 percent of the fluctuations in the actual output gap. Estimates during periods of unusually persistent and unpredictable productivity shocks, as would be the case with increased climatic disruption, could be even worse.…”
Section: Climatic Disruption and Output Volatilitymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For example, using a New Keynesian model with imperfect information, Beckworth and Hendrickson (2016) show that the Fed's output gap forecasts over 1987-2007 explain only 13 percent of the fluctuations in the actual output gap. Estimates during periods of unusually persistent and unpredictable productivity shocks, as would be the case with increased climatic disruption, could be even worse.…”
Section: Climatic Disruption and Output Volatilitymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…There has been a great deal of renewed interest in nominal GDP targeting as suggested by Sumner (2014). Beckworth and Hendrickson (2015), for example, have examined interest rate rules where the central bank reacts to nominal GDP rather than to the inflation rate and GDP separately. They stress that such a rule has the advantage that the central bank does not have to estimate potential GDP, reflecting concerns raised by Orphanides (2003).…”
Section: How Have the Various Rules Suggested For Monetary Policy Chamentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Although economists disagree about how much emphasis to place on each deviation, the basic Taylor rule framework continues to be used by many economists—and policy makers—as a benchmark . Building on Koenig's () observation that a Taylor rule is just a special case of a nominal GDP (NGDP) targeting rule, this paper follows Beckworth and Hendrickson () and Selgin, Beckworth, and Bahadir () in applying a Taylor rule that responds to deviations of total money spending from a targeted growth path. Using NGDP to measure total money spending, this Taylor rule takes the following form: it=it*+ϕ1NGDPtGap+ϕ2true(normalΣi=112NGDPtiGap12true) where i t is the target interest rate, it* is the market‐clearing or equilibrium nominal interest rate, and NGDPtGap is the percentage difference between the actual and the targeted growth rate of NGDP.…”
Section: The Ecb's Role In the Eurozone Crisismentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Responding to the average of past misses gets around the thorny problem of constantly reestimating the trend growth path of NGDP. 27 For more on this point, see Beckworth and Hendrickson (2016). 28 Setting i * t equal to 1 plus the inflation forecast implies a real natural interest rate of 1%.…”
Section: Endnotesmentioning
confidence: 99%