1990
DOI: 10.1002/mar.4220070406
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Naïve theories of price: A developmental model

Abstract: A model of the development of naïve theories of price is presented and tested. The criterion used to account for price variations within a product category is product features at age five, product features and quality at age ten, product quality and buyer utility at age thirteen, and a combination of supply considerations and buyer utility/demand in adulthood. Five‐year‐olds do not justify their use of product features as a price criterion; however, older respondents all justify their price criterion by referr… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
20
0
2

Year Published

2010
2010
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
6
1

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 19 publications
(22 citation statements)
references
References 12 publications
0
20
0
2
Order By: Relevance
“…Specifically, a number of theoretical accounts attribute the scarcity bias to some understanding of how market dynamics affect object value (Amaldoss & Jain, ; Gierl et al, ; Lynn, ; Verhallen & Robben, ). Accordingly, one would have expected such a bias to emerge only at an age children have some such understanding—which is arguably by school‐age (Thompson & Siegler, ) or even early adolescence (Fox & Kehret‐Ward, ; John, ; Leiser & Beth‐Halachmi, ; Valkenburg & Cantor, ; Williams et al, ). Indeed, one experiment to date that assessed the development of a scarcity bias, documented its emergence at around age 10 (Echelbarger & Gelman, ), another at 7 (Diesendruck et al, ), and a third at 6 (but only with unknown items, either in a competitive context, or only among boys is noncompetitive ones; John et al, ).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Specifically, a number of theoretical accounts attribute the scarcity bias to some understanding of how market dynamics affect object value (Amaldoss & Jain, ; Gierl et al, ; Lynn, ; Verhallen & Robben, ). Accordingly, one would have expected such a bias to emerge only at an age children have some such understanding—which is arguably by school‐age (Thompson & Siegler, ) or even early adolescence (Fox & Kehret‐Ward, ; John, ; Leiser & Beth‐Halachmi, ; Valkenburg & Cantor, ; Williams et al, ). Indeed, one experiment to date that assessed the development of a scarcity bias, documented its emergence at around age 10 (Echelbarger & Gelman, ), another at 7 (Diesendruck et al, ), and a third at 6 (but only with unknown items, either in a competitive context, or only among boys is noncompetitive ones; John et al, ).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…According to these “derived” accounts, children should manifest a scarcity bias by the age they are capable of understanding such social and economic factors. By most estimates, this would be around 7‐years at the earliest, as this is the age at which an understanding of the relation between market dynamics and object value starts to appear (Thompson & Siegler, ), though such an understanding consolidates by early adolescence (Fox & Kehret‐Ward, ; John, ; Leiser & Beth‐Halachmi, ; Valkenburg & Cantor, ; Williams, Ashill, & Thirkell, ).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…We developed methods that isolated scarcity effects from those of salience, and also developed ways to test for scarcity preference in chimpanzees. We tested children aged 4 and 6 because in this age range they are not yet familiar with prices and the relationship between economic variables such as supply and demand (Fox & Kehret‐Ward, , ; John, ; Leiser, ).…”
Section: Evolutionary and Ontogenetic Origins Of A Scarcity Preferencementioning
confidence: 99%
“…Plus tard, l'enfant affine son raisonnement et des attributs fonctionnels, comme la qualité, complètent son évaluation des prix. A partir de 13 ans, il devient capable d'abstraction et peut juger les prix en les contextualisant (Fox et Kehret Ward, 1990), c'est-àdire en intégrant des variables d'environnement (e.g. l'image-prix du magasin ou les attentes du destinataire du produit) dans son évaluation.…”
Section: L'enfant : Un Consommateur En Cours De Socialisationunclassified
“…proposition 8). Les caractéristiques du produit (Damay, 2008a ;Fox et Kehret-Ward, 1990 ;Melkman et al, 1981 ;Tversky, 1985).…”
Section: La Place Du Prix Selon Les Différents Rôles De L'enfant-consunclassified