2008
DOI: 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2008.07.003
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Moral hazard in insurance, value-based cost sharing, and the benefits of blissful ignorance

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

2
67
0
1

Year Published

2009
2009
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
6
1
1

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 66 publications
(70 citation statements)
references
References 13 publications
(10 reference statements)
2
67
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…Insurance design is further complicated by the likely reality that patients often Insurance design is further complicated by the likely reality that patients often do not act as far-sighted rational consumers. Pauly and Blavin (2008) note that in do not act as far-sighted rational consumers. Pauly and Blavin (2008) note that in value-based insurance design, optimal cost-sharing should be determined not just value-based insurance design, optimal cost-sharing should be determined not just by a comparison of true resource costs and associated improvements in health; in by a comparison of true resource costs and associated improvements in health; in particular, if many patients are short-sighted or myopic and undervalue certain particular, if many patients are short-sighted or myopic and undervalue certain types of care, cost-sharing for that care could be reduced.…”
Section: Value-based Design Value-based Designmentioning
confidence: 96%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Insurance design is further complicated by the likely reality that patients often Insurance design is further complicated by the likely reality that patients often do not act as far-sighted rational consumers. Pauly and Blavin (2008) note that in do not act as far-sighted rational consumers. Pauly and Blavin (2008) note that in value-based insurance design, optimal cost-sharing should be determined not just value-based insurance design, optimal cost-sharing should be determined not just by a comparison of true resource costs and associated improvements in health; in by a comparison of true resource costs and associated improvements in health; in particular, if many patients are short-sighted or myopic and undervalue certain particular, if many patients are short-sighted or myopic and undervalue certain types of care, cost-sharing for that care could be reduced.…”
Section: Value-based Design Value-based Designmentioning
confidence: 96%
“…Phelps and Mooney (1993) analyzed utilization of medical services are less clear. Phelps and Mooney (1993) analyzed utilization of common, and expensive, procedures in hospitals around the state of New York. of common, and expensive, procedures in hospitals around the state of New York.…”
Section: Cross-price Effects Cross-price Effectsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Pauly and Blavin (2008) and Baicker, Mullainathan, and Schwartzstein (2015) summarize evidence that people have a systematic propensity to under-or overuse certain treatments at the margin. For example, Choudhry et al (2011) document that many recent heart attack victims do not adhere to drug Handel and Kolstad (2015b) "Uninformed" consumers leave substantial dollars on table when "over-choosing" generous insurance coverage, relative to "informed" consumers.…”
Section: Consumer Ignorance and Misinformation In Health Marketsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Baicker, Mullainathan, and Schwartzstein (2015) argue that it is difficult to rationalize such examples in a framework where consumers accurately trade off health benefits against the copay. Others argue that consumer misinformation is likely a key reason why consumers act as if they misweight treatment benefits (for example, Pauly and Blavin 2008). These findings have important policy implications: in many cases, when consumers make poor health choices it both increases long-run health costs and reduces consumer health, and everyone loses.…”
Section: Health Treatmentmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The uncertainty of medical spending gives rise to the demand for health insurance (Arrow, 1963); at the same time, the presence of moral hazard implies that full insurance is not optimal and consumers should remain liable for some spending through deductibles and/or coinsurance (Pauly, 1968). Exactly how much risk consumers should face in order to achieve an efficient outcome depends on both the price elasticity of demand for medical care and on the quality of their information about the effectiveness of different medical treatments (Chernew, Rosen, and Fendrick, 2007;Pauly and Blavin, 2008). In the real world, determining the optimal level of coinsurance is further complicated by the significant tax subsidy to employment-related health insurance, in which health insurance premiums paid by employers are not taxed as income to employees, an arrangement which very likely results in coinsurance rates that are suboptimally low for many people-that is, they face too little risk from an efficiency perspective (Feldstein, 1973;Feldstein and Friedman, 1977).…”
Section: How Much Medical Spending Risk Should Households Face?mentioning
confidence: 99%