2011
DOI: 10.1007/s13209-011-0052-9
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Majority relation and median representative ordering

Abstract: This paper presents results on the transitivity of the majority relation and the existence of a median representative ordering. Building on the notion of intermediate preferences indexed by a median graph, the analysis extends well-known results obtained when the underlying graph is a line. In contrast with other types of restrictions such as single-peakedness, intermediate preferences allow for a clear distinction between restrictions on the set of preferences characteristics and those on the set of alternati… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
4
1

Citation Types

0
24
0

Year Published

2013
2013
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
5

Relationship

0
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 15 publications
(24 citation statements)
references
References 12 publications
0
24
0
Order By: Relevance
“…This result is remarkable in particular in view of the fact that quite a number of nonsingle-peaked Condorcet domains have been identified in the literature, among others the domains satisfying Sen's 'value restriction' condition (Sen [1966]) with the 'single-dipped' domain (Inada [1964]) as a special case, the domains satisfying the so-called 'intermediateness' property (Grandmont [1978], Demange [2012]), and the 'order-restricted' domains identified by Rothstein [1990]; the latter domains are sometimes also referred to as the domains with the single-crossing property (Gans and Smart [1996], Saporiti [2009], Puppe and Slinko [2015]). Our analysis shows that none of these domains can jointly satisfy the three conditions of minimal richness, connectedness and the inclusion of a pair of completely reversed orders unless it is also single-peaked.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 82%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…This result is remarkable in particular in view of the fact that quite a number of nonsingle-peaked Condorcet domains have been identified in the literature, among others the domains satisfying Sen's 'value restriction' condition (Sen [1966]) with the 'single-dipped' domain (Inada [1964]) as a special case, the domains satisfying the so-called 'intermediateness' property (Grandmont [1978], Demange [2012]), and the 'order-restricted' domains identified by Rothstein [1990]; the latter domains are sometimes also referred to as the domains with the single-crossing property (Gans and Smart [1996], Saporiti [2009], Puppe and Slinko [2015]). Our analysis shows that none of these domains can jointly satisfy the three conditions of minimal richness, connectedness and the inclusion of a pair of completely reversed orders unless it is also single-peaked.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 82%
“…22 Some authors such as, e.g., Grandmont [1978] and Demange [2012] refer to orders that are between two others in this sense as 'intermediate' orders.…”
Section: A1 the Case Of Linear Ordersmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Independently of this work Demange (2011) has developed some ideas quite similar to the ones presented here. She introduces a notably different set-up, in which a median graph represents the relation of the different preference orderings in a profile.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 93%
“…From the literature it is known that the existence of a Condorcet winner can be extended to single-peaked preferences on tree graphs (Demange 1982). For the characterization of Condorcet winners there are contributions in the field of location theory: For a special class of preferences, Wendell and McKelvey (1981) show that on tree graphs Condorcet winners coincide with the appropriately defined median; Bandelt and Barthélémy (1984) extend this result to so-called cube-free median graphs.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation