2013
DOI: 10.3386/w19212
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Linear Social Interactions Models

Abstract: This paper provides a systematic analysis of identification in linear social interactions models. This is both a theoretical and an econometric exercise as the analysis is linked to a rigorously delineated model of interdependent decisions. We develop an incomplete information game that describes individual choices in the presence of social interactions. The equilibrium strategy profiles are linear. Standard models in the empirical social interactions literature are shown to be exact or approximate special cas… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
52
1

Year Published

2013
2013
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
6
1
1

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 34 publications
(53 citation statements)
references
References 36 publications
0
52
1
Order By: Relevance
“…This contrasts with part of the literature on social interactions (e.g. Blume et al (2011)). In an economy where individuals are not ex-ante connected in a network, it seems unlikely that all of the individuals' characteristics are common knowledge.…”
Section: Global Analysiscontrasting
confidence: 47%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…This contrasts with part of the literature on social interactions (e.g. Blume et al (2011)). In an economy where individuals are not ex-ante connected in a network, it seems unlikely that all of the individuals' characteristics are common knowledge.…”
Section: Global Analysiscontrasting
confidence: 47%
“…The identification of β, σ ε and λ, given G, follows from standard results for linear models (see Blume et al (2011) or Lee et al (2010)). …”
Section: Peer Effects and Extracurricular Activitiesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Although the reflection problem was an important issue in the early peer-effects literature, since it prompted researchers to think carefully about model specification and identification, it has since become clear that it applies mostly to a sort of simple reduced-form model, and is not an issue in many other micro-founded models. For instance, as emphasized by Blume, Brock, Durlauf, and Ioannides (2011) and Blume, Brock, Durlauf, and Jayaraman (2015), the reflection problem is functional form dependent -not applying to many nonlinear models, and being even nongeneric in linear models. An additional, complemetary, insight is that network information, rather than only group-level information, can enable identification, as then the full feedback patterns pointed out by Manski (1993) can be disentangled by taking advantage of the fact that different individuals have different sets of peers, and therefore different exposures and net effects, as shown by Bramoullé, Djebbari, and Fortin (2009).…”
Section: Endogeneity Of Network and Other Empirical Challengesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Finally, I should also point out that this special structure delivers a direct dependence of the outcome variable y on the KatzBonacich centrality index for each individual atβ, listed in the vector (I −βW ) −1β W 1 if the "peer effect" effort depends on the degree of the individual (i.e., α = 0). Blume, Brock, Durlauf, and Jayaraman (2015) focus their analysis on a different payoff structure corresponding to a narrative where individuals have preference for conformity. As they point out, the models are observationally equivalent.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…One way in which that condition is satisfied is if W is block-diagonal with at least two blocks of different order. Suppose, for example, that the social network is comprised of two complete subgraphs of size N 1 and N 2 such that 14 Exogenous covariates x l and (observed) contextual effects on those can be accomodated (see Blume, Brock, Durlauf, and Jayaraman (2015)), but are ommitted as in Graham (2008).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%