2004
DOI: 10.1016/s0165-4896(03)00069-6
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

L.S. Penrose's limit theorem: proof of some special cases

Abstract: L.S. Penrose was the first to propose a measure of voting power (which later came to be known as 'the [absolute] Banzhaf (Bz) index'). His limit theorem-which is implicit in his booklet (1952) and for which he gave no rigorous proof-says that in simple weighted voting games (WVGs), if the number of voters increases indefinitely while the quota is pegged at half the total weight, then-under certain conditions-the ratio between the voting powers (as measured by him) of any two voters converges to the ratio betwe… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

5
50
0

Year Published

2004
2004
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
5
3

Relationship

2
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 63 publications
(55 citation statements)
references
References 6 publications
5
50
0
Order By: Relevance
“…However, Lindner and Machover [4] show by means of a simple counterexample that these conditions are insufficient for Penrose's approximation formula and the version of Penrose's Limit Theorem implied by it. On the other hand, they prove the approximation formula (in a somewhat improved form) as well as Penrose's Limit Theorem under more stringent conditions: both with respect to β for q = 1 2 (see [4,Theorem 3.6]); and with respect to the Shapley-Shubik index φ for arbitrary q ∈ (0, 1) (see [4,Theorem 2.3]).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…However, Lindner and Machover [4] show by means of a simple counterexample that these conditions are insufficient for Penrose's approximation formula and the version of Penrose's Limit Theorem implied by it. On the other hand, they prove the approximation formula (in a somewhat improved form) as well as Penrose's Limit Theorem under more stringent conditions: both with respect to β for q = 1 2 (see [4,Theorem 3.6]); and with respect to the Shapley-Shubik index φ for arbitrary q ∈ (0, 1) (see [4,Theorem 2.3]).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…On the other hand, they prove the approximation formula (in a somewhat improved form) as well as Penrose's Limit Theorem under more stringent conditions: both with respect to β for q = 1 2 (see [4,Theorem 3.6]); and with respect to the Shapley-Shubik index φ for arbitrary q ∈ (0, 1) (see [4,Theorem 2.3]). …”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…3.1 of this article. 34 In the limit, when the number of members goes to infinity, this optimal quota tends to 1/2, in agreement with the PLT (see Lindner and Machover 2004). 35 The Constitutional rule is now also known as the Lisbon rule as it was the one selected for the CM in the Treaty of Lisbon 2007.…”
Section: Application To the Eu Council Of Ministersmentioning
confidence: 84%
“…The latter states that under certain conditions and if the distribution of weights is not too skewed (in other words, the ratio of the largest weight to the smallest is not very high), then the relative powers of the voters tend to approximate closely to their respective relative weights. Lindner and Machover 2004;Lindner 2004;Lindner and Owen 2007 provide proofs for some special cases with respect to the Penrose-Banzhaf measure as well as the Shapley-Shubik index. In other words, when PLT holds the voters' voting weights are with close approximation proportional to their Penrose-Banzhaf measures (Shapley-Shubik indices).…”
Section: Committees Of Representativesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Conversely, when the equation = has solutions and ∈ 1 × , + = and = can be obtained relying on the Penrose theorem [9,10].…”
Section: The Equationmentioning
confidence: 99%