1999
DOI: 10.1029/1998wr900094
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Improving the ability of a water market to efficiently manage drought

Abstract: Abstract. Some water markets maintain institutional elements that provide allocative advantages to specified water users. In the Lower Rio Grande Valley, water rights are designated as either municipal or agricultural (irrigation), with certain prioritization advantages afforded to municipal accounts. While sales of rights between municipalities and irrigators are allowed, the priority disparity results in a prohibition on leasing between sectors. Concern over meeting future urban demand has led municipalities… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
48
0
1

Year Published

2009
2009
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
9
1

Relationship

1
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 47 publications
(49 citation statements)
references
References 8 publications
0
48
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…This policy is typical for dry regions such as the Mediterranean Basin Region, the South-Western US and the Far East (Characklis et al 1999;Molle and Berkoff 2006;Hoyer 2010). Satisfactory water allocation between the municipal and the agricultural sectors, subject to their rights, has become a crucial problem (World Bank 1999, Chapter 8, p 85;Megdal et al 2009).…”
Section: The Quarrel Between the Agricultural And The Urban Sectorsmentioning
confidence: 98%
“…This policy is typical for dry regions such as the Mediterranean Basin Region, the South-Western US and the Far East (Characklis et al 1999;Molle and Berkoff 2006;Hoyer 2010). Satisfactory water allocation between the municipal and the agricultural sectors, subject to their rights, has become a crucial problem (World Bank 1999, Chapter 8, p 85;Megdal et al 2009).…”
Section: The Quarrel Between the Agricultural And The Urban Sectorsmentioning
confidence: 98%
“…In the past few decades, water markets have been proposed as a policy instrument to improve the efficiency of water use, becoming an effective and relevant mechanism in addressing water shortage problems in different regions of Australia, California and Chile [3,[72][73][74][75]; indeed, by providing a price for water markets to make the opportunity cost of water explicit to users, promoting voluntary transfers from less efficient users to those who could use water more productively and providing incentives for irrigators and other water users to preserve water and adopt water-saving technologies [76,77].…”
Section: Concluding Remarks and Future Researchmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Several articles dealing with such tools have been published, e.g. for integrated river basin management to simulate the economic impacts of policies in drought periods (Characklis et al, 1999;Booker et al, 2005), to quantify the economic value of stream flow (PulidoVelazquez et al, 2006(PulidoVelazquez et al, , 2008, for policy options and water allocation (Letcher et al, 2004), for trade-offs between competing uses (Burke et al, 2004), for analysis of the impact of climatic changes (Tanaka et al, 2006), and for trade-offs between efficiency, equity and sustainability in the design of water programs (Ward and Pulido-Velazquez, 2008). IWRM drives individual sectors to coordinate actions and collaborate with each other and enhances stakeholder participation, transparency and cost effective local management (Mylopoulos and Kolokytha, 2008).…”
Section: The Need Of Integrated Water Resources Managementmentioning
confidence: 99%