2014
DOI: 10.1086/676316
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Implications of an Economic Theory of Conflict: Hindu-Muslim Violence in India

Abstract: for useful discussions, and to Steve Wilkinson for granting us access to a dataset on religious conflict. We thank Jay Dev Dubey for his able research assistance. We are grateful to five anonymous referees for their valuable comments. We particularly thank Co-Editor Jesse Shapiro, who went beyond the call of duty in his detailed reading of the manuscript, making many constructive suggestions that greatly improved both the content and the exposition. ABSTRACTWe model inter-group conflict driven by economic chan… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

2
67
0

Year Published

2015
2015
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
4
4
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 149 publications
(82 citation statements)
references
References 30 publications
2
67
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Similarly, analyses of conflict have been expanded to consider interactions between different kinds of contestants, for instance conflicts between state and non-state actors (de Mesquita, 2013;Powell, 2013;Fearon, 2011;Esteban et al, 2015) or between ethnic groups (Esteban and Ray, 2011;Esteban et al, 2012;Mitra and Ray, 2014), and a number of papers consider the influence of third-parties on conflict frequency and outcomes (Baliga and Sjöström, 2012;Hörner et al, 2015;Dekel and Wolinsky, 2012). We describe these papers in somewhat more detail below.…”
Section: Contest Modelsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Similarly, analyses of conflict have been expanded to consider interactions between different kinds of contestants, for instance conflicts between state and non-state actors (de Mesquita, 2013;Powell, 2013;Fearon, 2011;Esteban et al, 2015) or between ethnic groups (Esteban and Ray, 2011;Esteban et al, 2012;Mitra and Ray, 2014), and a number of papers consider the influence of third-parties on conflict frequency and outcomes (Baliga and Sjöström, 2012;Hörner et al, 2015;Dekel and Wolinsky, 2012). We describe these papers in somewhat more detail below.…”
Section: Contest Modelsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Esteban et al (2012) confirm the expected effects empirically, leading to a more nuanced understanding of conflict as a mixture of "greed" over private prizes and "grievance" over the allocation of public goods among groups. Mitra and Ray (2014) study Hindu-Muslim conflict in India and find evidence that conflict is increasing in Muslim wealth, though they do not claim to know which side is instigating in response.…”
Section: Contest Modelsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…7 Thus, the monetary value of the few positions in the bureaucracy which were available could motivate "individuals … to fight in order to control the state and hence the sources of rent it gives access to". 8 The fact that the south remained structurally poor and dependent on remittance from the "productive" parts of the country seems to support instances of corruption in the system. If, for instance, a region privileged over others in terms of infrastructure was not been able to build a sustainable local economic base, it could be said that this infrastructural investment must have been mostly inappropriately, unsustainably or not actually carried out.…”
Section: Economic Causes:-mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The standard rational choice approach to modelling con ‡ict is to use a contest success function (see Gar…nkel and Skaperdas (2007) for an overview) or predator/prey models (see Mitra and Ray (2014) for an example) in which both approaches endogenise e¤ort levels expended on con ‡ict. In contrast, this model considers a simple binary choice of con ‡ict or peace, where the costs and bene…ts are …xed.…”
Section: The Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%