2020
DOI: 10.1007/s11129-020-09226-7
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

How to generalize from a hierarchical model?

Abstract: Models of consumer heterogeneity play a pivotal role in marketing and economics, specifically in random coefficient or mixed logit models for aggregate or individual data and in hierarchical Bayesian models of heterogeneity. In applications, the inferential target often pertains to a population beyond the sample of consumers providing the data. For example, optimal prices inferred from the model are expected to be optimal in the population and not just optimal in the observed, finite sample. The population mod… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

0
4
0

Year Published

2022
2022
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
5
1

Relationship

2
4

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 12 publications
(4 citation statements)
references
References 34 publications
0
4
0
Order By: Relevance
“…We adopt the marginal-conditional decomposition in Pachali, Kurz, and Otter (2020) to sign-constrain the budget and price coefficients in line with economic theory in the flexible S-component mixture of normals hierarchical prior/random coefficient distribution:…”
Section: Random Coefficient Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…We adopt the marginal-conditional decomposition in Pachali, Kurz, and Otter (2020) to sign-constrain the budget and price coefficients in line with economic theory in the flexible S-component mixture of normals hierarchical prior/random coefficient distribution:…”
Section: Random Coefficient Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…We adopt the marginal-conditional decomposition in Pachali, Kurz, and Otter (2020) to sign-constrain the budget and price coefficients in line with economic theory in the flexible S-component mixture of normals hierarchical prior/random coefficient distribution: where normalZ ¯ normali is row i of the demeaned matrix of financial demographic variables, such as disposable income and liquid funds; Δ* relates demographics to budget, price, and remaining demand coefficients (as suggested by, e.g., Petrin [2002]); false( μ normals * , normalV normals * false) are component-specific mean and variance-covariance parameters; and η s measures the weight of mixture component s. We need to take into account that Δ* is estimated on the log scale, and Web Appendix B shows how to arrive at the estimates of the relationship between demographics and sign-constrained demand parameters. We decide the number of mixture components (S) in the empirical application by comparing approximations to the marginal likelihood of different model specifications (similarly to the approach proposed in Dubé, Hitsch, and Rossi [2010]).…”
Section: Model Developmentmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Taken together, when now comparing the willingness to pay for the more sustainable with that for the less sustainable alternative, as perceived market share shifts from the 28 While here the coefficients 𝛽 i,k are assumed to be normally distributed, we note that for the sustainbility attribute(s) also order (sign) constraints would be appropriate, so that 𝛽 i,sust ≥ 0. We have also estimated the model by substituting the respective coefficients by e 𝛽 i,sust , albeit we have thereby used a Bayesian approach (implementing the techniques and code developed in Pachali et al [2020]). The values for the (expected) willingness-to-pay, including for the interactive term, are largely comparable.…”
Section: Relating the Data To Our Model Of Consumer Preferencesmentioning
confidence: 99%