2011
DOI: 10.1016/j.jesp.2011.02.013
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Honesty pays: On the benefits of having and disclosing information in coalition bargaining

Abstract: People typically think of negotiations as competitive, which often leads them to engage in secrecy and even deception. In three experiments we show that this approach can backfire in coalition bargaining. Results show that, even though bargainers with an outcome advantage only obtain favorable outcomes when this information is public, they rarely choose to reveal this information. Fairness motivations fueled decisions to reveal this information and make attractive offers whereas self-interest fueled decisions … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
25
0
3

Year Published

2012
2012
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
9
1

Relationship

1
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 25 publications
(28 citation statements)
references
References 60 publications
0
25
0
3
Order By: Relevance
“…Several researchers have employed a modified version of the UG with hidden information conditions in order to dissociate between altruistic and strategic considerations in UG offers (Kagel et al, 1995 ; van Dijk et al, 2004 ; van Beest et al, 2011 ). Hidden information refers to information that is only available to the proposer and that can be used in his/her own benefit.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Several researchers have employed a modified version of the UG with hidden information conditions in order to dissociate between altruistic and strategic considerations in UG offers (Kagel et al, 1995 ; van Dijk et al, 2004 ; van Beest et al, 2011 ). Hidden information refers to information that is only available to the proposer and that can be used in his/her own benefit.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, we also assume that people generally prefer to negotiate honestly, such that they will use deception only when they are unable to realize their desired outcomes through honest communication and action (Koning et al., ). These assumptions find support in recent research showing that people demonstrate some aversion to the use of deception—even when the economic benefits of deception exceed the economic costs of deception (Erat & Gneezy, ; Koning et al., ; Lundquist et al., ; Van Beest, Steinel, & Murnighan, )—and prefer to avoid situations that offer them the opportunity to deceive others (Shalvi, Handgraaf, & De Dreu, ). In this “instrumental perspective” on deception, “bargainers (a) will use deception as a means to reach their goals in bargaining but (b) will refrain from using deception when they have alternative means to reach their goals” (Koning et al., , p. 57).…”
Section: The Interpersonal Emotion Deception Model (Iedm)mentioning
confidence: 67%
“…However, proposers were deceptive only 60 times, and responders were deceptive only 61 times. These and other studies demonstrate that individuals have an aversion to engaging in deception even when there are clear economic benefits and little or no costs to doing so (Erat & Gneezy, ; Lundquist, Ellingsen, Gribbe, & Johannesson, ; Schweitzer, Ordóñez, & Douma, ; Van Beest, Steinel, & Murnighan, ). In fact, in some cases, individuals even opt to avoid situations that offer the opportunity to deceive others (Shalvi, Handgraaf, & De Dreu, ).…”
Section: Antecedents Of Deceptionmentioning
confidence: 67%