Our system is currently under heavy load due to increased usage. We're actively working on upgrades to improve performance. Thank you for your patience.
1995
DOI: 10.2307/2235156
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Herd Behaviour, Bubbles and Crashes

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
4

Citation Types

20
577
0
8

Year Published

2010
2010
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
5
4

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 929 publications
(605 citation statements)
references
References 16 publications
20
577
0
8
Order By: Relevance
“…In contrast to the more elaborate treatment in Lux (1995Lux ( , 1997, this reasoning, which can also be found in Lux (1998, p. 149), is sufficient for an infinite population. A rigorous mathematical argument that begins with a finite population size and the intrinsic noise it implies is spelled out in Franke (2008aFranke ( or 2008b.…”
mentioning
confidence: 90%
“…In contrast to the more elaborate treatment in Lux (1995Lux ( , 1997, this reasoning, which can also be found in Lux (1998, p. 149), is sufficient for an infinite population. A rigorous mathematical argument that begins with a finite population size and the intrinsic noise it implies is spelled out in Franke (2008aFranke ( or 2008b.…”
mentioning
confidence: 90%
“…Again with this approach, abrupt declines in stock prices can occur without any real change in the underlying fundamentals. Lux (1995) linked the phenomena of market crashes to the process of phase transition from thermodynamics and modeled the emergence of bubbles and crashes as a result of herd behavior among heterogeneous traders in speculative markets. Finally, a strand of literature documenting precursory patterns and log-periodic signatures years before the largest crashes in the modern history suggested that crashes have an endogenous origin in 'crowd' behavior and through the interactions of many agents (Sornette and Johansen, 1998;Johansen et al, 2000;Sornette, 2002Sornette, , 2004.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Hong and Stein (1999) developed a framework where the interaction between informed traders (newswatchers), and uninformed (momentum) traders, both with constant absolute risk aversion (CARA) and bounded rationality, are able to explain the commonly found initial underreaction to an information release followed by a subsequent overreaction to a series of information releases. This stream of research stimulated the development in recent years of a literature in heterogeneous agent-based models (HAM), comprising financial markets populated with agents who are neither fully-rational nor utilise the full information set (see also Brock and Hommes, 1997;1998, Lux, 19951998, Brock and LeBaron, 1996, Farmer and Joshi, 2002, and Iori, 2002. Many of these models have relied on computational methods to evaluate the impact on the price formation process of different beliefs about the future evolution of prices (see He and Li, 2008) and incorporated learning processes based on the relationship between market prices and available information.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…One common element of these various models is that they attribute the learning process directly to the clients, who evaluate the performance of their investment strategies, and consequently adapt by switching from a poor performing strategy to another which on recent evidence offers more promise (see for instance, Lux, 1995;1998, andMarchesi, 1999;2000). In contrast, the paper by Berk and Green (2004) propose a model where where clients react to past managerial performance.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%