1988
DOI: 10.2307/1912708
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Hedonic Prices and the Benefits of Public Projects

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
38
0
1

Year Published

1996
1996
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
3
3
2

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 86 publications
(40 citation statements)
references
References 8 publications
1
38
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…In contrast both to one recent interpretation of these models as identifying a vague "capitalization effect" that mixes information from different equilibria (Klaiber andSmith 2013, Kuminoff andPope 2014) and to another interpretation of them as identifying a Marshallian welfare measure (Greenstone and Gallagher 2008), I show that the estimand defined by difference-in-differences hedonics has a clear interpretation as a lower bound on the Hicksian equivalent surplus for a non-marginal change in characteristics, even when general equilibrium effects are present. The bound is analogous to measures first suggested by Bartik (1988) and Kanemoto (1988). The bound is valid under a much wider set of condi-tions that those of Section 2.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 61%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…In contrast both to one recent interpretation of these models as identifying a vague "capitalization effect" that mixes information from different equilibria (Klaiber andSmith 2013, Kuminoff andPope 2014) and to another interpretation of them as identifying a Marshallian welfare measure (Greenstone and Gallagher 2008), I show that the estimand defined by difference-in-differences hedonics has a clear interpretation as a lower bound on the Hicksian equivalent surplus for a non-marginal change in characteristics, even when general equilibrium effects are present. The bound is analogous to measures first suggested by Bartik (1988) and Kanemoto (1988). The bound is valid under a much wider set of condi-tions that those of Section 2.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 61%
“…In this model, even with heterogeneity, predicted changes in prices along a constant hedonic price function still represent non-marginal CV and EV. Palmquist's (1992) model is actually a limiting case of the model discussed by Bartik (1988) and Kanemoto (1988). Bartik and Kanemoto showed that, in general, even if the hedonic price function does shift, and even if there are adjustments in housing attributes, aggregate predicted price changes using the ex ante hedonic price function represent an upper bound on welfare changes.…”
Section: Using Only the First Stage To Evaluate Non-marginal Changes mentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…An alternative proposed independently by Bartik (1988) and Kanemoto (1988) Comparison of the upper and lower bounds with our WTP estimates provides another gauge of the importance of general equilibrium adjustments for benefit estimates derived from large scale environmental changes. We compare the bounds with our WTP estimates by county.…”
Section: Comparison To Hedonic Upper and Lower Boundsmentioning
confidence: 96%
“…It has long been understood that analogues of classic revealed preference arguments apply to hedonic prices (see for example Scotchmer (1985), Kanemoto (1988), Pollak (1989), and Pakes (2003)). These papers show that hedonic prices can be used to bound willingness to pay 1 Also related are papers studying hedonic prices in competitive markets in labor economics (Sattinger (1995), Leeth and Ruser (2003)), in environmental economics (Freeman (1995), Smith and Huang (1995), Chay and Greenstone (2005), Sieg et al (2004)) and urban and public economics (Epple and Sieg (1999)).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%