2005
DOI: 10.1016/j.geb.2004.11.003
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Gamson's Law versus non-cooperative bargaining theory

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

3
36
0
2

Year Published

2009
2009
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
6
3

Relationship

1
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 81 publications
(43 citation statements)
references
References 15 publications
3
36
0
2
Order By: Relevance
“…They too find that coalition member shares are more equal than predicted under the SSPE, and that a majority of, but not all, allocations are for minimal winning coalitions. In a series of papers, Fréchette et al (2005aFréchette et al ( , 2005bFréchette et al ( , 2005c) study the Baron-Ferejohn model and compare it with demand bargaining (Morelli 1999) and Gamson's Law (Gamson 1961), using closed amendment rule procedures and an infinite time horizon. Their main findings are that there is support for the qualitative implications of the Baron-Ferejohn model, but serious deviations from the point predictions of the model, as proposer power is far less than predicted under the stationary subgame perfect equilibrium.…”
Section: Extent Of Agreement On Proposalsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…They too find that coalition member shares are more equal than predicted under the SSPE, and that a majority of, but not all, allocations are for minimal winning coalitions. In a series of papers, Fréchette et al (2005aFréchette et al ( , 2005bFréchette et al ( , 2005c) study the Baron-Ferejohn model and compare it with demand bargaining (Morelli 1999) and Gamson's Law (Gamson 1961), using closed amendment rule procedures and an infinite time horizon. Their main findings are that there is support for the qualitative implications of the Baron-Ferejohn model, but serious deviations from the point predictions of the model, as proposer power is far less than predicted under the stationary subgame perfect equilibrium.…”
Section: Extent Of Agreement On Proposalsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…He shows that a belief-based learning model based on Friedman and Cheung (1997) can account for these trends. Frechette et al (2005aFrechette et al ( , 2005b report results from an experiment designed to test the separate e¤ects of bargaining power and recognition power, in a legislature with di¤erent sized parties who have strong party discipline (i.e., always vote as a block). Bargaining power is measured directly in terms of the size of the voting block.…”
Section: Bf Experimentsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This is not true empirically, a finding first published over 40 years ago. 6 Nonetheless, GL itself has proved extraordinarily robust to replication, even when different cabinet portfolios are assigned very 4 (Bassi 2013;Carroll and Cox 2007a;Laver et al 2011;Warwick and Druckman 2006;Falcó-Gimeno and Indridason 2013) 5 Browne and Franklin 1973;Browne and Frendreis 1980;Fréchette et al 2005b;Gamson 1961;Laver et al 2011;Schofield and Laver 1985;Warwick and Druckman 2006;Snyder et al 2005) different empirical weights. 7 On the other side of the paradox we find canonical alternating offers models of legislative bargaining, with an intellectual pedigree traceable to Rubinstein (1982), adapted to legislative bargaining by Baron and Ferejohn (1989 .…”
Section: The Paradoxmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The second proposition is stated ex post, knowing the identity of the formateur. The propositions are therefore not contradictory because they apply in 7 Browne and Franklin 1973;Browne and Frendreis 1980;Fréchette et al 2005b;Gamson 1961;Laver et al 2011;Schofield and Laver 1985;Warwick and Druckman 2006;Snyder et al 2005) 8 Snyder et al 2005) 9 (Snyder et al 2005: 982) 10 (Snyder et al 2005: 992) different settings, but this highlights a critical distinction between ex ante and ex post models of cabinet portfolio distribution. The paradox is therefore both simple and striking.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%