2017
DOI: 10.1137/16m1109102
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Game Options in an Imperfect Market with Default

Abstract: We study pricing and superhedging strategies for game options in an imperfect market with default. We extend the results obtained by Kifer in [23] in the case of a perfect market model to the case of an imperfect market with default, when the imperfections are taken into account via the nonlinearity of the wealth dynamics. We introduce the seller's price of the game option as the infimum of the initial wealths which allow the seller to be superhedged. We prove that this price coincides with the value function … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

2
43
0

Year Published

2018
2018
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
6
1

Relationship

2
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 26 publications
(45 citation statements)
references
References 23 publications
(56 reference statements)
2
43
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Let us now comment on the existing approaches to the nonlinear valuation of derivatives, as first developed by El and El and later applied by several authors to particular financial models or classes on contracts (see, for instance, Bichuch et al (2018), Brigo and Pallavicini (2014), Crépey (2015a, b), Dumitrescu et al (2017), Mercurio (2013) or Pallavicini et al (2012a, b)). The most common approach to the valuation problem in a nonlinear framework seems to hinge, at least implicitly, on the following steps in which it is usually assumed that the hedger's initial endowment is immaterial and thus it may be set to zero.…”
Section: No-arbitrage Pricing Principlesmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Let us now comment on the existing approaches to the nonlinear valuation of derivatives, as first developed by El and El and later applied by several authors to particular financial models or classes on contracts (see, for instance, Bichuch et al (2018), Brigo and Pallavicini (2014), Crépey (2015a, b), Dumitrescu et al (2017), Mercurio (2013) or Pallavicini et al (2012a, b)). The most common approach to the valuation problem in a nonlinear framework seems to hinge, at least implicitly, on the following steps in which it is usually assumed that the hedger's initial endowment is immaterial and thus it may be set to zero.…”
Section: No-arbitrage Pricing Principlesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Note, however, that if the wealth process happens to be governed by some simple dynamics with no portfolio constraints or trading adjustments, then there is no need to postulate that this property holds, since it can be deduced from a suitable comparison theorem for ordinary differential equations. For a particular example of a model where Assumption 4 is satisfied, see Lemma 6.2 in the paper by (Dumitrescu et al 2017) who postulate that the wealth process satisfies…”
Section: Assumption 4 For Every C ∈ C and T ∈ [0 T ) All X T P T mentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…where f 2 t := f 1 t − A t . Let us apply for fixed ω a comparison result for forward differential equations (see [8] in the Appendix).…”
Section: American Option Pricing From the Seller's Point Of Viewmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Indeed, no rational agent would pay more than u 0 since there is a cheaper way to achieve at least the same payoff, whatever the exercise time is. Indeed, by investing the amount u 0 + ε and following the strategy ϕ * , whatever the exercise time ν is, he will make the gain V u 0 +ε,ϕ * ν > V u 0 ,ϕ * ν (≥ ξ ν ) a.s. by a strict comparison property for deterministic differential equations (see [8] in the Appendix). Moreover, if the price of the option is equal to u 0 +ε, then, by investing this amount following the strategy ϕ * , whatever the exercise time ν is, the seller will make a gain V u 0 +ε,ϕ * ν −ξ ν > 0 a.s.…”
Section: American Option Pricing From the Seller's Point Of Viewmentioning
confidence: 99%