2010
DOI: 10.1007/s11127-010-9648-z
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Free riders, holdouts, and public use: a tale of two externalities

Abstract: Free riders and holdouts are market failures that potentially impede the completion of otherwise beneficial transactions. The key difference is that the free rider problem is a demand side externality that requires taxation to compel payment for a public good, while the holdout problem is a supply side externality that requires eminent domain to force the sale of land for large scale projects. This paper highlights that distinction between these two problems and uses the resulting insights to clarify the meani… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

0
9
0
1

Year Published

2013
2013
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
5
1

Relationship

1
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 14 publications
(10 citation statements)
references
References 14 publications
0
9
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…That is, when sellers are strategic holdouts, the developer knows he will acquire the properties through eminent domain, but when sellers are not strategic holdouts the developer knows he must acquire the properties through market exchange or not at all. On the other hand, if the regulator chooses "non-holdouts too" then it may be rational for the developer 10 We follow Miceli (2011) in assuming that the regulator can distinguish between homeowners who holdout for strategic versus sincere reasons. A "strategic holdout" is a property seller who is willing to accept the developer's price yet holds out in order to redistribute more of the bargaining surplus from the developer to the homeowner.…”
Section: Developer's Incentivesmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 4 more Smart Citations
“…That is, when sellers are strategic holdouts, the developer knows he will acquire the properties through eminent domain, but when sellers are not strategic holdouts the developer knows he must acquire the properties through market exchange or not at all. On the other hand, if the regulator chooses "non-holdouts too" then it may be rational for the developer 10 We follow Miceli (2011) in assuming that the regulator can distinguish between homeowners who holdout for strategic versus sincere reasons. A "strategic holdout" is a property seller who is willing to accept the developer's price yet holds out in order to redistribute more of the bargaining surplus from the developer to the homeowner.…”
Section: Developer's Incentivesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This conditional justification raises the question of how best to arrange institutional constraints in order to promote the efficient use of eminent domain. Miceli (2011) argues that the Kelo court arrived at the efficient legal rule, albeit for the incorrect reason. On the contrary, in light of our analysis, the Kelo ruling should be viewed as inefficient insofar as regulators use their discretionary 13 Much of James M. Buchanan's work sought to dismantle the implicit "benevolent despot" assumption that ran through most standard models in neoclassical public finance.…”
Section: Problem With the Holdout Problemmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 3 more Smart Citations